Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO AND INNOVATIVE PERFORMANCE OF BRAZILIAN INDUSTRY

ABSTRACT

The main objective of this study is to analyze the relationship between Alliance Portfolio Diversity (APD) and the firm's innovative performance, especially when R&D capacity (RDCAP) and Specialized Complementary Assets (SCA) moderate this relationship at different points in the firm's value chain; the study also identifies the nature of the relationship between such moderators. It applies econometric methods to a database comprised of 13,020 companies from Brazilian industry. The results reveal an inverted U-shaped curvilinear relationship between APD and innovative performance, as well as the effective positive moderation of this relationship by the RDCAP and the SCA. This research contributes to the literature on firm knowledge, especially theories of open innovation and absorptive capacity (AC). The former is progressing to emerging economic contexts and the second, contributing a new way of understanding AC by investigating its spatial dimensions, in addition to the skills and competencies dimensions.

KEYWORDS
Alliance portfolio diversity; innovative performance; R&D capacity; specialized complementary assets; firm's value chain

RESUMO

O principal objetivo deste artigo é analisar o relacionamento entre a Diversidade do Portfólio de Alianças (DPA) e o desempenho inovador da firma, especialmente quando esse relacionamento é moderado pela capacidade de P&D (CAPPD) e pelos Ativos Complementares Especializados (ACE) em pontos distintos de sua cadeia de valor, bem como identificar a natureza da relação existente entre tais moderadores. Métodos econométricos foram aplicados a uma base de dados composta por 13.020 empresas da indústria brasileira. Os resultados mostraram relação curvilinear em forma de U-invertido entre a DPA e o desempenho inovador, bem como a efetiva moderação positiva desse relacionamento, por parte da CAPPD e dos ACE. Esta pesquisa contribui para a literatura que aborda o conhecimento da firma, especialmente para as teorias da inovação aberta e da capacidade de absorção (CA), a primeira avançando em direção aos contextos econômicos emergentes e a segunda adicionando uma nova forma de compreender a CA, que pode ser investigada também a partir de suas dimensões espaciais, além das dimensões de habilidades e competências.

PALAVRAS-CHAVE
Diversidade de portfólio de alianças; desempenho inovador; capacidade de P&D; ativos complementares especializados; cadeia de valor da firma

RESUMEN

El objetivo principal de este documento es analizar la relación entre la diversidad de portafolio de alianzas (DPA) y el desempeño innovador de la empresa, especialmente cuando esa relación está moderada por la capacidad de I&D (CAPID) y los activos complementarios especializados (ACE), en puntos distintos de su cadena de valor, así como identificar la naturaleza de la relación entre dichos moderadores. Los métodos econométricos se aplicaron a una base de datos compuesta por 13.020 empresas de la industria brasileña. Los resultados mostraron una relación curvilínea en forma de U invertida entre la DPA y el desempeño innovador, así como la moderación positiva efectiva de esta relación por parte de la CAPID y los ACE. Esta investigación contribuye a la literatura que aborda el conocimiento de la empresa, especialmente para las teorías de innovación abierta y capacidad de absorción (CA). Para la primera, al avanzar hacia contextos económicos emergentes y para la segunda, al agregar una nueva forma de entender la CA, que también puede investigarse desde sus dimensiones espaciales, además de las dimensiones de habilidades y competencias.

PALABRAS CLAVE
Diversidad de portafolio de alianzas; desempeño innovador; capacidad de I&D; activos complementarios especializados; cadena de valor de la firma

INTRODUCTION

The knowledge-based literature on firms is rich in analyses of organizational environments and mechanisms related to firms' strategies of accessing various types of knowledge (Benner & Tushman, 2003Benner, M. J., & Tushman, M. L. (2003). Exploitation, exploration, and process management: The productivity dilemma revisited. Academy of Management Review, 28(2), 238-256. doi: 10.2307/30040711
https://doi.org/10.2307/30040711...
; Cohen & Levinthal, 1990Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(3), 128-152. doi:10.1177/0149206310369939
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310369939...
; March, 1991March, J. G. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2(1), 71. doi:10.1287/orsc.2.1.71
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2.1.71...
). These analyses consolidate the importance of accessing knowledge and technologies in a firm's external sources (Chesbrough, 2003Chesbrough, H. W. (2003). Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from technology(Vol. 2.006). Boston, USA: Harvard Business School Press. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8691.2008.00502.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8691.2008...
, 2006Chesbrough, H. W. (2006). Open business models: How to thrive in the new innovation landscape. Boston, USA: Harvard Business Review Press.). The greater the range of knowledge or technologies accessed, the greater are the chances that the firm develops new combinations of knowledge and ideas. However, this implies that the firm's absorptive capacity (AC) also has to increase (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(3), 128-152. doi:10.1177/0149206310369939
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310369939...
; Zahra & George, 2002Zahra, S. A., & George, G. (2002). Absorptive capacity: A review, reconceptualization, and extension. Academy of Management Review. 17(2), 185-203. doi:10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995
https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995...
).

These considerations lead to the specific context of the Alliance Portfolio Diversity (APD) (Faems, Visser, Andries, & Looy, 2010Faems, D., Visser, M. De, Andries, P., & Looy, B. Van. (2010). Technology alliance portfolios and financial performance: Value-enhancing and cost-increasing effects of open innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27(6), 785-796. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00752.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010...
) as a driver of the firm's innovative performance. This study defines APD considering portfolio as a set of formal active alliances of the focal firm (Baum et al., 2000Baum, J. A. C.; Calabrese,T.; Silverman, B. S. (2000). Don't go it alone: alliance network composition and startups' performance in canadian biotechnology. Strategic Management Journal 21, 267-294. doi: 10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(200003)21:33.0.CO;2-8
https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(...
; Leeuw, Lokshin, & Duysters, 2014Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
) and diversity as the distribution of differences among these alliances, in relation to an attribute "X" (Leeuw et al., 2014Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
). Regarding this topic, the literature has investigated the characteristics and relationships with partners (Lavie & Miller, 2008Lavie, D., & Miller, S. R. (2008). Alliance portfolio internationalization and firm performance. Organization Science, 19(4), 623-646. doi:10.1287/orsc.1070.0341
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1070.0341...
; Leeuw et al., 2014Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
) and the characteristics of the resources and knowledge involved (Asgari, Singh, & Mitchell, 2017Asgari, N., Singh, K., & Mitchell, W. (2017). Alliance portfolio reconfiguration following a technological discontinuity. Strategic Management Journal, 38, 1062-1081. doi: 10.1002/smj.2554
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2554...
; Srivastava & Gnyawali, 2011Srivastava, M. K., & Gnyawali, D. R. (2011). When do relational resources matter? Leveraging technological resources for breakthrough innovation. Academy of Management Journal, 54(4), 797-810. doi: 10.5465/AMJ.2011.64870140
https://doi.org/10.5465/AMJ.2011.6487014...
; Vasudeva & Anand, 2011Vasudeva, G., & Anand, J. (2011). Unpacking absorptive capacity: A study of knowledge utilization from alliance portfolios. Academy of Management Journal, 54(3), 611-623. doi: 10.5465/amj.2011.61968108
https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2011.6196810...
). Further, the literature has examined the management of tasks and tools (Oerlemans, Knoben, & Pretorius, 2013Oerlemans, L. A. G., Knoben, J., & Pretorius, M. W. (2013). Alliance portfolio diversity, radical and incremental innovation: The moderating role of technology management. Technovation, 33(6-7), 234-246. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2013.02.004
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2...
) and the frequency of new strategic and tactical competitive actions (Andrevsky, Brass, & Ferrier, 2016Andrevsky, G., Brass, D. J., & Ferrier, W. J. (2016) Alliance portfolio configurations and competitive action frequency. Journal of Management, 42(4), 811-837. doi: 10.1177/0149206313498901
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206313498901...
). The functions, relationships, and routines of alliance portfolio management have also been studied in relation to public institutions (Milagres, Rezende, & Silva, 2017Milagres, R., Rezende, O., & Silva, S. A. G. (2017). Papel e posição do departamento de alianças: Caso Embrapa. Revista de Administração Pública, 51(3), 431-450 doi:10.1590/0034-7612160046
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612160046...
).

However, correlating partner diversification with the existence of resources along a firm's value chain has been little explored, especially in emerging economic scenarios where companies exhibit low adherence to open innovation practices (Bogers, Burcharth, & Chesbrough, 2019Bogers, M., Burcharth, A., & Chesbrough, H. (2019). Open innovation in Brazil: Exploring opportunities and challenges. International Journal of Innovation, 7(2), 178-191. doi: 10.5585/iji.v7i2.417.2318-9975
https://doi.org/10.5585/iji.v7i2.417.231...
). Idiosyncrasies related to the protection of intellectual property, immature industrial standards, as well as a weakening of social capital, help explain such contexts, including the Brazilian one (Bogers et al., 2019Bogers, M., Burcharth, A., & Chesbrough, H. (2019). Open innovation in Brazil: Exploring opportunities and challenges. International Journal of Innovation, 7(2), 178-191. doi: 10.5585/iji.v7i2.417.2318-9975
https://doi.org/10.5585/iji.v7i2.417.231...
). To address this academic gap, this study postulates that successful innovation requires capabilities existing upstream of the value chain-in terms of R&D activities-and capabilities downstream of the value chain, where market-related activities occur (Bruyaka & Durand, 2012Bruyaka, O., & Durand, R. (2012). Sell-off or shut-down? Alliance portfolio diversity and two types of high tech firms' exit. Strategic Organization, 10(1), 7-30. doi: 10.1177/1476127011432366
https://doi.org/10.1177/1476127011432366...
; Rothaermel & Hill, 2005Rothaermel, F. T., & Hill, C. W. L. (2005). Technological discontinuities and complementary assets: A longitudinal study of industry and firm performance. Organization Science, 16(1), 52-70. doi: 10.1287/orsc.1040.0100
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1040.0100...
).

Bruyaka and Durand (2012)Bruyaka, O., & Durand, R. (2012). Sell-off or shut-down? Alliance portfolio diversity and two types of high tech firms' exit. Strategic Organization, 10(1), 7-30. doi: 10.1177/1476127011432366
https://doi.org/10.1177/1476127011432366...
showed the simultaneous existence of exploration and exploitation activities at different stages of a firm's value chain, which involves the development of different organizational units and also contradictory organizational processes (Benner & Tushman, 2003Benner, M. J., & Tushman, M. L. (2003). Exploitation, exploration, and process management: The productivity dilemma revisited. Academy of Management Review, 28(2), 238-256. doi: 10.2307/30040711
https://doi.org/10.2307/30040711...
). These activities aim to invent a novelty, as well as to create the structure and strategy for launching it into the market (Rothaermel & Deeds, 2004Rothaermel, F. T., & Deeds, D. L. (2004). Exploration and exploitation alliances in biotechnology: A system of new product development. Strategic Management Journal, 25(3), 201-221. doi:10.1002/smj.376
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.376...
). Therefore, in the context of an alliance portfolio, different partners provide different types of knowledge and skills (Leeuw et al., 2014Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
) at different points of a firm's value chain (Bruyaka & Durand, 2012Bruyaka, O., & Durand, R. (2012). Sell-off or shut-down? Alliance portfolio diversity and two types of high tech firms' exit. Strategic Organization, 10(1), 7-30. doi: 10.1177/1476127011432366
https://doi.org/10.1177/1476127011432366...
). Thus, firms face trade-offs between the interactions and distribution of costs and the benefits generated by these activities (March, 1991March, J. G. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2(1), 71. doi:10.1287/orsc.2.1.71
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2.1.71...
). With high levels of variability, the rising costs related to integrating new knowledge can outweigh the benefits (Faems et al., 2010Faems, D., Visser, M. De, Andries, P., & Looy, B. Van. (2010). Technology alliance portfolios and financial performance: Value-enhancing and cost-increasing effects of open innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27(6), 785-796. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00752.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010...
).

Thus, the main objective of this study is to understand the relationship between APD and a firm's innovative performance, incorporating investments in R&D capacity (RDCA) and Specialized Complementary Assets (SCA) as moderating organizational factors. RDCA occurs predominantly at the beginning of the firm's value chain and the SCA along the chain and at the end of it. It is assumed that such organizational factors will positively moderate the relationship between costs and benefits generated by APD, as well as clarify the relationship between these organizational factors. Based on data from the Innovation Research database (Pintec) of the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE), this study incorporated a sample of 13,020 Brazilian companies belonging to 5 sectors of the extractive industry and 24 sectors of the manufacturing industry. The results show substantial support for the hypothesis of an inverted U-shaped relationship between APD and innovative performance, as well as for the hypotheses regarding the moderating effects. The hypothesis that predicted a positive relationship between the moderating factors was refuted.

THEORY AND HYPOTHESES

According to the concept of open innovation, a firm can exploit knowledge developed by a partner or can license its own knowledge to other partners so they can exploit it (Chesbrough, 2003Chesbrough, H. W. (2003). Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from technology(Vol. 2.006). Boston, USA: Harvard Business School Press. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8691.2008.00502.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8691.2008...
; Huizingh, 2011Huizingh, E. K. R. E. (2011). Open innovation: State of the art and future perspectives. Technovation, 31(1), 2-9. doi:10.1016/j.technovation.2010.10.002
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2...
). Through these channels, the firm creates and disseminates new knowledge throughout the organization, embedding it in products, services, and systems (Caloghirou, Kastelli, & Tsakanikas, 2004Caloghirou, Y., Kastelli, I., & Tsakanikas, A. (2004). Internal capabilities and external knowledge sources: Complements or substitutes for innovative performance? Technovation, 24(1), 29-39. doi: 10.1016/S0166-4972(02)00051-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0166-4972(02)00...
). Contact with and absorption of knowledge originating from many agents that are external to the organization are important (Katila, 2002Katila, R. (2002). New product search over time: Past ideas in their prime? Academy of Management Journal, 45(5), 995-1010. doi: 10.2307/3069326
https://doi.org/10.2307/3069326...
; Laursen & Salter, 2006Laursen, K., & Salter, A. (2006). Open for innovation: The role of openness in explaining innovation performance among U.K. manufacturing firms. Strategic Management Journal, 27(2), 131-150. doi:10.1002/smj.507
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.507...
, 2014Laursen, K., & Salter, A. J. (2014). The paradox of openness: Appropriability, external search and collaboration. Research Policy, 43(5), 867-878. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2013.10.004
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2013.10...
), since only a few can generate viable combinations (Nelson & Winter, 1982Nelson, R., & Winter, S. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, USA: The Belknapp Press of Harvard University Press.).

Leeuw et al. (2014)Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
highlight studies that address the importance of diversity of competencies and skills accessed externally. Examples of this are suppliers improving production processes, process innovations, and cost reductions (Sobrero & Roberts, 2002Sobrero, M., & Roberts, E. B. (2002). Strategic management of supplier-manufacturer relations in new product development. Research Policy, 31(1), 159-182. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00157-8
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00...
), or customers and consumers feedback reducing the uncertainty associated with new product introductions, market expansions, and adaptations to existing products and services (Tether, 2002Tether, B. S. (2002). Who co-operates for innovation, and why: An empirical analysis. Research Policy, 31(6), 947-967. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00172-X
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00...
). Other examples include competitors allowing access to industry-specific knowledge and sharing costs/research facilities (Kim & Higgins, 2007Kim, J. W., & Higgins, M. C. (2007). Where do alliances come from?. The effects of upper echelons on alliance formation. Research Policy, 36(4), 499-514. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2007.02.017
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2007.02...
), and universities and public research institutes generating new scientific and technological knowledge (Leeuw et al., 2014Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
).

Therefore, developing a portfolio of alliances can be an important strategy for an innovative firm; such a portfolio is the set of all types of strategic alliances that a firm currently maintains, as well as those it developed in the past.

Only some partnerships will be viable; this implies that AC reflects a "firm's ability to recognize the value of new and external information, assimilate it and apply it for commercial purposes" (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(3), 128-152. doi:10.1177/0149206310369939
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310369939...
, p. 128). Assimilating and applying information for commercial purposes indicates that AC should not be a construct restricted to creating a new product (R&D), but also to producing and marketing it. The concept of AC reviewed by Zahra and George (2002)Zahra, S. A., & George, G. (2002). Absorptive capacity: A review, reconceptualization, and extension. Academy of Management Review. 17(2), 185-203. doi:10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995
https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995...
emphasizes the skills of acquisition and assimilation of new and external knowledge-potential AC-and the skills of transformation and exploration of this knowledge-realized AC. This approach establishes two conditions implicit in the concepts of potential AC and realized AC: a) they are different from each other, and b) they occur at different times. The theoretical view of the "functional diversity of a firm's partners in their different positions in its value chain" (Bruyaka & Durand, 2012Bruyaka, O., & Durand, R. (2012). Sell-off or shut-down? Alliance portfolio diversity and two types of high tech firms' exit. Strategic Organization, 10(1), 7-30. doi: 10.1177/1476127011432366
https://doi.org/10.1177/1476127011432366...
, p. 9) incorporates a third condition: the aforementioned skills are acquired at different stages in the firm's value chain.

Decisions to invest in RDCA, as well as in certain SCA, can be critical to the development of an alliance portfolio. The first type of investment, upstream in the chain, enables the firm to identify the partner that generates more benefits than costs when accessing new knowledge/technology-potential AC (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(3), 128-152. doi:10.1177/0149206310369939
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310369939...
; Zahra & George, 2002Zahra, S. A., & George, G. (2002). Absorptive capacity: A review, reconceptualization, and extension. Academy of Management Review. 17(2), 185-203. doi:10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995
https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995...
). The second type of investment, downstream in the chain, enables the firm to identify the partner that generates more benefits than costs when accessing the market-realized AC (Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
; Zahra &George, 2002Zahra, S. A., & George, G. (2002). Absorptive capacity: A review, reconceptualization, and extension. Academy of Management Review. 17(2), 185-203. doi:10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995
https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995...
). "Innovative firms without manufacturing requirements and related capacities may die, even if they are the best in innovation" (Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
, p. 285). Thus, ensuring that the appropriate type of external knowledge is absorbed at different points in the firm's value chain presupposes the existence of diversity in the focal firm's partners.

Organizations that try to balance such very different activities have to reconcile very different internal subunits that are not substantially integrated with each other in terms of structure (Benner & Tushman, 2003Benner, M. J., & Tushman, M. L. (2003). Exploitation, exploration, and process management: The productivity dilemma revisited. Academy of Management Review, 28(2), 238-256. doi: 10.2307/30040711
https://doi.org/10.2307/30040711...
). This management challenge is highly likely to emerge in APD contexts. As the complexity of its alliance portfolio increases, the organization needs to develop functions and relationships at its corporate level, in an area especially dedicated to alliances (Faems et al., 2010Faems, D., Visser, M. De, Andries, P., & Looy, B. Van. (2010). Technology alliance portfolios and financial performance: Value-enhancing and cost-increasing effects of open innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27(6), 785-796. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00752.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010...
; Milagres et al., 2017Milagres, R., Rezende, O., & Silva, S. A. G. (2017). Papel e posição do departamento de alianças: Caso Embrapa. Revista de Administração Pública, 51(3), 431-450 doi:10.1590/0034-7612160046
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612160046...
). This increases the number of tasks and skills required and, consequently, changes the firm's internal cost structure (Faems et al., 2010Faems, D., Visser, M. De, Andries, P., & Looy, B. Van. (2010). Technology alliance portfolios and financial performance: Value-enhancing and cost-increasing effects of open innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27(6), 785-796. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00752.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010...
; Kale & Singh, 2009Kale, P., & Singh, H. (2009). Managing strategic alliances: What do we know now, and where do we go from here? Academy of Management Perspectives, 23(3), 45-62. doi:10.5465/AMP.2009.43479263
https://doi.org/10.5465/AMP.2009.4347926...
).

These costs are related to the creation of relationships and communication networks between the firm and the external environment. The reliability of knowledge can be negatively affected, as the firm's capacity to correctly assimilate new knowledge decreases if the diversity of alliances increases excessively (Lee, 2007Lee, G. K. (2007). The significance of network resources in the race to enter emerging product markets: The convergence of telephony communications and computer networking, 1989-2001. Strategic Management Journal, 28, 17-37. doi:10.1002/smj.566
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.566...
). Further, the resulting profit can also be negatively impacted, especially when this increase in diversity is related to speedy and regular portfolio expansion (Hashai, Kafouros, & Buckley, 2018Hashai, N., Kafouros, M., & Buckley, P. J. (2018) The performance implications of speed, regularity, and duration in alliance portfolio expansion. Journal of Management, 44(2), 707-731.). Faems et al. (2010)Faems, D., Visser, M. De, Andries, P., & Looy, B. Van. (2010). Technology alliance portfolios and financial performance: Value-enhancing and cost-increasing effects of open innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27(6), 785-796. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00752.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010...
concluded that APD positively impacted the innovative performance of 305 Belgian manufactures but the increase in portfolio diversity triggered additional control and monitoring costs that made the net effect negative. Jiang, Tao, and Santoro (2010)Jiang, R. J., Tao, Q. T., & Santoro, M. D. (2010). Research notes and commentaries alliance portfolio diversity and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal., 31, 1136-1144. doi:10.1002/smj.869
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.869...
found results showing the cancellation of the benefit provided by the last partner added to the alliance portfolio of 138 multinationals in the global automotive industry. Therefore, based on the aforementioned contexts and considering the theoretical and empirical contributions reviewed here, the first hypothesis of the present study is as follows:

H1: APD has an inverted U-shaped relationship with a firm's innovative performance.

The knowledge-based view of the firm attributes the significance of R&D routines not only as an activity that creates the firm's knowledge but also as an activity that develops its AC (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(3), 128-152. doi:10.1177/0149206310369939
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310369939...
; Jong & Freel, 2010Jong, J. P. J. De, & Freel, M. (2010). Absorptive capacity and the reach of collaboration in high technology small firms. Research Policy, 39(1), 47-54. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2009.10.003
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2009.10...
). Therefore, R&D initiatives are activities often considered to have a positive relationship with the firm's innovative performance, including the development of competitive advantages (Andrevsky et al., 2016Andrevsky, G., Brass, D. J., & Ferrier, W. J. (2016) Alliance portfolio configurations and competitive action frequency. Journal of Management, 42(4), 811-837. doi: 10.1177/0149206313498901
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206313498901...
; Cassiman & Veugelers, 2006Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in innovation strategy: Internal R&D and external knowledge acquisition. Management Science, 52(1), 68-82. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470
https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470...
).

On the other hand, the uncertainty and often irrecoverable costs associated with innovation are also automatically associated with R&D activities. Due to these levels of uncertainty, R&D activities are often conducted on a cooperative basis (Chesbrough, 2003Chesbrough, H. W. (2003). Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from technology(Vol. 2.006). Boston, USA: Harvard Business School Press. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8691.2008.00502.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8691.2008...
). Nevertheless, according to Oxley (1997)Oxley, J. (1997). Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: A transaction-cost approach. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 13(2), 387-409. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a023389
https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.j...
, hierarchical alliances are chosen when ownership risks are high.

If firms whose knowledge or technologies are complementary form an R&D partnership (Cassiman & Veugelers, 2006Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in innovation strategy: Internal R&D and external knowledge acquisition. Management Science, 52(1), 68-82. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470
https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470...
; Tsai & Wang, 2008Tsai, K. H., & Wang, J. C. (2008). External technology acquisition and firm performance: A longitudinal study. Journal of Business Venturing, 23(1), 91-112. doi:10.1016/j.jbusvent.2005.07.002
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2005....
), the combination of their technologies will occur in a more straightforward and efficient way, which in most cases can generate incremental innovations. If, on the contrary, the partner firms' technologies are substitutes (Laursen & Salter, 2006Laursen, K., & Salter, A. (2006). Open for innovation: The role of openness in explaining innovation performance among U.K. manufacturing firms. Strategic Management Journal, 27(2), 131-150. doi:10.1002/smj.507
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.507...
), the interactions between the two partners' R&D areas can generate redundant knowledge or technology, generating irrecoverable costs and few possibilities for new combinations. However, substitutability may be preferable when it increases flexibility and provides a firm with a greater possibility to develop more exploratory combinations (Dibiaggio, Nasiriyar, & Nesta, 2014Dibiaggio, L., Nasiriyar, M., & Nesta, L. (2014). Substitutability and complementarity of technological knowledge and the inventive performance of semiconductor companies. Research Policy, 43(9), 1582-1593. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2014.04.001
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2014.04...
) and, therefore, have more possibilities to arrive at unprecedented knowledge (March, 1991March, J. G. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2(1), 71. doi:10.1287/orsc.2.1.71
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2.1.71...
).

Despite the inconclusive results of studies on complementarity and substitutability (Ceccagnoli, Higgins, & Palermo, 2014Ceccagnoli, M., Higgins, M. J., & Palermo, V. (2014). Behind the scenes: Sources of complementarity in R&D. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 23(1), 125-148. doi:10.1111/jems.12048
https://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12048...
), this study emphasizes the complementarity between firms' R&D areas for three reasons: a) the "path-dependent" nature of knowledge or innovation (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(3), 128-152. doi:10.1177/0149206310369939
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310369939...
; March, 1991March, J. G. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2(1), 71. doi:10.1287/orsc.2.1.71
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2.1.71...
); b) the wide predominance of incremental innovations in the Brazilian industry (Pintec, 2011); and, c) the critical importance of the firm's AC (Ceccagnoli et al., 2014Ceccagnoli, M., Higgins, M. J., & Palermo, V. (2014). Behind the scenes: Sources of complementarity in R&D. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 23(1), 125-148. doi:10.1111/jems.12048
https://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12048...
), especially in APD environments.

Thus, the higher a firm's level of investment in internal R&D upstream in its chain, the greater its potential CA is (Spithoven & Teirlinck, 2015Spithoven, A., & Teirlinck, P. (2015). Internal capabilities, network resources and appropriation mechanisms as determinants of R&D outsourcing. Research Policy, 44(3), 711-725. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2014.10.013
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2014.10...
). Subsequently, its alliance portfolio may be more diverse or effective. Therefore, the positive moderation of investments in RDCA manifests as a "smoothing out" of the curvilinear relationship between a firm's APD and its innovative performance. In other words, despite their costs, such investments allow extending the advantageous condition of the innovative performance that diversified partners provide. Hence the second hypothesis proposed is as follows:

H2: A firm's RDCA positively moderates the curvilinear relationship between the firm's APD and its innovative performance.

In innovation contexts, "almost all successful cases of commercializing an innovation require that the knowledge in question be used together with other complementary capabilities or assets" (Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
, p. 288). Complementary Assets (CA) are, therefore, activities related to specialized capacities in manufacturing, marketing, access to distribution channels, after-sales, service networks, and complementary technologies (Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
). In a framework of fragile intellectual property (such as the Brazilian framework), if the product is easily imitated and the CA are generic, the firm will not have to make large investments, as the product and CA will be available in the industry. However, if the CA are specialized, the firm that owns them will have a clearly advantageous position (Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
). Thus, cooperation emerges, either initiated by a small innovative firm that needs SCA (as in the biotechnology and pharmaceutical market) (Rothaermel, 2001Rothaermel, F. T. (2001). Incumbent's advantage through exploiting complementary assets via interfirm cooperation. Strategic Management Journal, 22(6-7), 687-699. doi:10.1002/smj.180
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.180...
) or by the large firm that owns the SCA. Among the main incentives to license an external technology, there are three categories of CA that positively moderate a firm's technological diversification strategy and the firm's performance: marketing resources, production resources, and human capital (Chiu, Lai, Lee, & Liaw, 2008Chiu, Y. C., Lai, H. C., Lee, T. Y., & Liaw, Y. C. (2008). Technological diversification, complementary assets, and performance. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 75(6), 875-892. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2007.07.003
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2007....
).

Therefore, the more a firm invests in SCA-downstream in its value chain-the more effective its APD can be, which will positively impact its innovative performance. Because they are specialized, SCA take time to be developed or imitated (Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
) and are, therefore, important drivers of a firm's decision to engage in alliances. Thus, the positive moderation of investments in SCA manifests as a "smoothing out" of the curvilinear relationship between a firm's APD and its innovative performance. In other words, despite their costs, such investments allow extending the advantageous condition of the innovative performance that diversified partners provide. Thus, the third hypothesis proposed is as follows:

H3: A firm's SCA positively moderate the curvilinear relationship between the firm's APD and its innovative performance.

In conclusion, if the two moderating variables are organizational factors located at different points in the firm's chain, the most likely way that synergistic activities are truly beneficial is that the relationship between these two factors should be complementary. If a firm adopts one strategy, the marginal return of another strategy also increases if the two strategies are complementary. Similarly, if these strategies are substitutes for each other, an increase in one activity reduces the marginal benefit of the other (Cassiman &Veugelers, 2006Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in innovation strategy: Internal R&D and external knowledge acquisition. Management Science, 52(1), 68-82. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470
https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470...
; Hagedoorn & Wang, 2012Hagedoorn, J., & Wang, N. (2012). Is there complementarity or substitutability between internal and external R&D strategies? Research Policy, 41(6), 1072-1083. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2012.02.012
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.02...
), which incurs costs for redundant results.

Teece (1986)Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
attributed important implications to a firm's R&D strategy as a result of the firm's investments in SCA, reinforcing the concept of complementarity between these two variables. Therefore, a firm's SCA condition its decisions regarding investments in R&D (Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
) in response to technological changes, acting both as resources that lessen the effects of these changes and as prisms through which the firms visualize these changes. Thus, they determine the amount and direction in which the firm will invest in these resources (Wu, Wan, & Levinthal, 2014Wu, B., Wan, Z., & Levinthal, D. A. (2014). Complementary assets as pipes and prisms: Innovation incentives and trajectory choices. Strategic Management Journal, 35(9), 1257-1278. doi:10.1002/smj.2159
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2159...
).

The simultaneous search for knowledge at the various stages of the firm's value chain "provides the basis for unique resource combinations that can become sources of superior performance" (Hess & Rothaermel, 2011Hess, A. M., & Rothaermel, F. T. (2011). When are assets complementary? Star scientists, strategic alliances, and innovation in the pharmaceutical industry. Strategic Management Journal, 32(8), 895-909. doi:10.1002/smj.916
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.916...
, p. 906). This statement also indicates the hypothesis of complementarity between upstream and downstream activities, which impacts the firm's innovative performance. This complementarity represents the effective connections between the organization's subunits, enabling firms to transition to a new technology (Taylor & Helfat, 2009Taylor, A., & Helfat, C. E. (2009). Organizational linkages for surviving technological change: Complementary assets, middle management, and ambidexterity. Organization Science, 20(4), 718-739. doi:10.1287/orsc.1090.0429
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1090.0429...
). From these observations emerges the fourth and last hypothesis of this study:

H4: Within the context of alliances between innovative firms, a firm's RDCA and SCAs are complementary variables to the extent that, when interacting, they have a positive impact on each other.

METHODS

Data

The database used in this study is Pintec, from IBGE. Until the data collection of this article, Pintec was composed of data from five trienniums, starting with 1998-2000 and ending with 2009-2011. Due to the limitations of the database related to the unavailability of research variables in older triennia, this study uses the last two triennia (2006-2008 and 2009- 2011). Based on the third edition of the Oslo Manual and on the model proposed by the Eurostat and Community Innovation Survey, Pintec offers "information regarding behavior, activities undertaken, impacts, incentives, obstacles and other factors related to the company as a whole (the innovative agent)" (IBGE, 2011Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística. (2011). Rio de Janeiro, Brasil: IBGE-PINTEC - Pesquisa de Inovação - triênios 2006-2008 e 2009-2011., p. 14).

The final sample included only innovative companies-according to IBGE, those that implemented at least one new or substantially improved product and/or process in the period studied. This framework is consistent with the fact that the dependent variable in the proposed model is the firm's innovative performance. In addition, to minimize the potential occurrence of selection bias, companies that developed innovative projects were also considered innovative, even if these projects were incomplete or abandoned within the studied period. Pintec provides variables taking several types of values-percentages, Likert scales, absolute values, and dichotomous values-which reduces the possibility of common method bias. As the data are part of two independent trienniums also helps to prevent this type of bias. The response rate exceeds 90% (IBGE, 2011Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística. (2011). Rio de Janeiro, Brasil: IBGE-PINTEC - Pesquisa de Inovação - triênios 2006-2008 e 2009-2011.), which minimizes non-response bias (Laursen & Salter, 2004Laursen, K., & Salter, A. (2004). Searching high and low: What types of firms use universities as a source of innovation? Research Policy, 33(8), 1201-1215. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2004.07.004
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2004.07...
). Despite precautions of this type, Pintec exhibits limitations with regard to the specificities of the innovative organizational environment, which, to some extent, can impact the obtained results.

Investigating the repetition frequency of individual entities (companies) in the three-year periods studied resulted in identifying 10,524 distinct companies distributed across the trienniums. Matching these companies with those in the final sample (13,020 companies) was done to identify whether the data could be considered as panel data. As it was unfeasible to use the data in panel format, a transversal study (pooled cross-sectional) of the data was decided, with the 2006-2008 and 2009 -2011 data being "stacked." Thus, the sample comprised 13,020 companies that met the "innovative" criterion. Based on another criterion, among the firms that developed an alliance portfolio as a cooperation strategy for innovation, those that considered this a high- or medium-magnitude strategy were selected. These companies are distributed across sectors CNAE 5 to CNAE 33 (National Classification of Economic Activities), with 5 and 24 sectors belonging to the extractive industry and the manufacturing industry, respectively.

Measurements

Dependent variable

Following Laursen and Salter (2006)Laursen, K., & Salter, A. (2006). Open for innovation: The role of openness in explaining innovation performance among U.K. manufacturing firms. Strategic Management Journal, 27(2), 131-150. doi:10.1002/smj.507
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.507...
and Berchicci (2013)Berchicci, L. (2013). Towards an open R&D system: Internal R&D investment, external knowledge acquisition and innovative performance. Research Policy, 42(1), 117-127. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2012.04.017
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.04...
, the dependent variable-innovative performance-was defined as the percentage of the firm's internal net sales related to product innovation, obtained by summing the relevant variables. Three questions in the questionnaire addressed these innovations with respect to their levels of originality, considering the national and world markets. The sum of the values of the corresponding variables is converted to the total percentage of sales corresponding to two types of product innovation: incremental and radical (TOTAL_IN). Because it is in percentage form, the dependent variable assumes values between 0 and 1.

Independent variable

The independent variable is APD. This variable was measured in a similar way as in Duysters and Lokshin (2011)Duysters, G., & Lokshin, B. (2011). Determinants of alliance portfolio complexity and its effect on innovative performance of companies. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 28(4), 570-585. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2011.00824.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2011...
, Faems et al. (2010)Faems, D., Visser, M. De, Andries, P., & Looy, B. Van. (2010). Technology alliance portfolios and financial performance: Value-enhancing and cost-increasing effects of open innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27(6), 785-796. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00752.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010...
, Oerlemans et al. (2013)Oerlemans, L. A. G., Knoben, J., & Pretorius, M. W. (2013). Alliance portfolio diversity, radical and incremental innovation: The moderating role of technology management. Technovation, 33(6-7), 234-246. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2013.02.004
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2...
, and Leeuw et al. (2014)Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
.

First, a cut-off criterion identified the question that defined which companies had been involved in cooperative arrangements, in a "yes" or "no" format. Then, using a second criterion, based on the questions that defined the degree of importance of this type of arrangement, the companies that indicated significant involvement were chosen, based on four response options (non-relevant, low, medium, and high). The APD variable was defined for the companies that considered their external cooperation activities to be of high or medium importance, taking a value of 1 for high and medium importance and 0 for the other response options.

In relation to a firm's partners' locations, the questionnaire questions corresponding to national partners were combined into a value of 1, while 0 was assigned to international partners. Subsequently, this information was added for the group of respondents who classified the cooperation as high and medium importance. The same logic, conversely, was applied to the response option of international partners. Thus, the APD variable was measured by the percentage of the number of partner types in a firm's portfolio out of the maximum possible number of types of partners. There are seven possible types of partners in the questionnaire (customers/consumers, suppliers, competitors, another company in the group, consulting companies, universities/institutes, and training centers and testing and certification institutions) and two possibilities for partner location (national or international). Thus, the maximum possible number of types of partners is 14 (7 x 2). The present study recognizes the limitation in how this variable was measured, in terms of the possibility of obtaining the same score from different combinations of partner types. Another possible bias is related to the difference in effectiveness among the different types of partners. Partnerships with universities, for example, tend to generate more basic knowledge (Trajtenberg, Henderson, & Jaffe, 1997Trajtenberg, M., Henderson, R., & Jaffe, A. (1997). University versus corporate patents: A window on the basicness of invention. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 5(1), 19-50. doi: 10.1080/10438599700000006
https://doi.org/10.1080/1043859970000000...
), that is, they are associated with more embryonic stages of technologies and, therefore, with more uncertainty (Ziedonis, 2007Ziedonis, A. A. (2007). Real options in technology licensing real options in technology licensing. Management Science, 53(10), 1618-1633.). However, the literature recognizes this form of measurement as valid, as in Oerlemans et al. (2013)Oerlemans, L. A. G., Knoben, J., & Pretorius, M. W. (2013). Alliance portfolio diversity, radical and incremental innovation: The moderating role of technology management. Technovation, 33(6-7), 234-246. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2013.02.004
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2...
and Leeuw et al. (2014)Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
.

Moderating variables

According to Berchicci (2013)Berchicci, L. (2013). Towards an open R&D system: Internal R&D investment, external knowledge acquisition and innovative performance. Research Policy, 42(1), 117-127. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2012.04.017
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.04...
, Cassiman and Veugelers (2002)Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2002). R&D cooperation and spillovers: Some empirical evidence from Belgium. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1169-1184. doi: 10.1257/00028280260344704
https://doi.org/10.1257/0002828026034470...
, and Escribano, Fosfuri, and Tribó (2009)Escribano, A., Fosfuri, A., & Tribó, J. A. (2009). Managing external knowledge flows: The moderating role of absorptive capacity. Research Policy, 38(1), 96-105. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2008.10.022
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2008.10...
, the variable RDCA is the ratio of two other variables from the Pintec questionnaire: a) the number of people dedicated exclusively and partially to R&D activities, according to their qualification levels (PhD, Master's, or Bachelor's degree) and b) the firm's net revenue. The ratio of these two variables aims to reduce the occurrence of sample bias due to firm size.

The SCA variable involves four ratios based on two variables from the Pintec questionnaire. The argument for applying these variables is justified by the theory presented in previous sections (Chiu et al., 2008Chiu, Y. C., Lai, H. C., Lee, T. Y., & Liaw, Y. C. (2008). Technological diversification, complementary assets, and performance. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 75(6), 875-892. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2007.07.003
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2007....
; Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
). The numerator for each ratio is each of the expenditures or investments (in monetary units) in the four types of SCA: a) acquisition of machinery and equipment, b) training, c) introduction of technological innovations in the market, and d) other preparations for production and distribution. Each of the four denominators is the total number of persons employed by the firm, once again aiming to correct the bias caused by firm size. The four different ratios are added together to obtain the value of the SCA variable.

Control variables

Since the regional and specific characteristics of the companies in the sample can affect the dependent variables assessed here, to capture the net effect of RDCA and SCA, the present study also considered a set of control variables. Therefore, to control for factors specific to the companies included in the sample, a sectoral control dummy variable that represents the difference between the two types of industries in the sample-the extractive industry and the processing industry (IND_TRANS)-was first used (Laursen & Salter, 2006Laursen, K., & Salter, A. (2006). Open for innovation: The role of openness in explaining innovation performance among U.K. manufacturing firms. Strategic Management Journal, 27(2), 131-150. doi:10.1002/smj.507
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.507...
). "Firm size" was also considered, as the logarithm of the firm's total number of employed persons (Laursen & Salter, 2014Laursen, K., & Salter, A. J. (2014). The paradox of openness: Appropriability, external search and collaboration. Research Policy, 43(5), 867-878. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2013.10.004
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2013.10...
). The variable "years" (YEAR), which defines one of the three-year periods as a basis for comparison, was also used. Another control variable was the role of the partnership or object of cooperation (RDFUN = R&D function), a variable controlled in the model, to account for the heterogeneity of the different types of accessed knowledge. The "origin of the controlling capital" (ORIGCAP) was another dummy control variable incorporated into the model to represent the impacts of the "internationalization" of the alliance portfolio on a firm's performance (Lavie & Miller, 2008Lavie, D., & Miller, S. R. (2008). Alliance portfolio internationalization and firm performance. Organization Science, 19(4), 623-646. doi:10.1287/orsc.1070.0341
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1070.0341...
). To control for the differences among R&D capacities, the variable "Internal R&D" (INTRD) was included, representing the firm's expenditures for internal R&D, in monetary units (Laursen & Salter, 2014). These expenditures were divided by the firm's total number of employed persons. Two other control variables included indicated whether the costs for the aforementioned activities were "financed by financial institutions" (FINPUB) or subsidized by the parent company (SUBSID). Another control variable indicated the "company's main market," that is, whether the firm was an exporter (EXPORT) or not. Finally, dummy variables (REGION) were used to capture time-invariant factors specific to each region.

Econometric model and estimation strategy

The dependent variable varies between 0 and 1 as it is a percentage; thus, it is a censored variable. A sample "where the returnee's information is only available for a few observations is known as a censored sample" (Gujarati & Porter, 2011Gujarati, D. N., & Porter, D. C. (2011). Econometria básica. Porto Alegre, Brasil: Amgh Editora. doi:10.1126/science.1186874
https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1186874...
, p. 571). Similarly, in the sample of innovative companies used in this study, there is a group of companies that declared themselves as innovative but did not declare any sales percentage related to innovative products. Such companies may have had other types of results corresponding to alternative responses in Pintec. For example, they may have reported an increase in the quality or variety of products offered, or a reduction in production costs. Therefore, a certain number of observations in the sample have no information about the respondent.

The econometric model suitable for this type of context is the Tobit model, a regression model with a censored dependent variable, estimated by maximum likelihood (Greene, 2003Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 97. doi:10.1198/jasa.2002.s458
https://doi.org/10.1198/jasa.2002.s458...
; Gujarati & Porter, 2011Gujarati, D. N., & Porter, D. C. (2011). Econometria básica. Porto Alegre, Brasil: Amgh Editora. doi:10.1126/science.1186874
https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1186874...
; Wooldridge, 2011Wooldridge, J. M. (2011). Introdução à econometria: Uma abordagem moderna. São Paulo: Cengage Learning.).

With regard to the statistical inconsistency resulting from endogeneity caused by bidirectional causality, studies on portfolios of alliances and innovation such as Oerlemans et al. (2013)Oerlemans, L. A. G., Knoben, J., & Pretorius, M. W. (2013). Alliance portfolio diversity, radical and incremental innovation: The moderating role of technology management. Technovation, 33(6-7), 234-246. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2013.02.004
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2...
did not reject the hypothesis of exogeneity of the regressors using the Durbin-Wu-Hausman test, demonstrating that the results presented in the next section tend to be statistically consistent.

However, studies such as Lavie and Miller (2008)Lavie, D., & Miller, S. R. (2008). Alliance portfolio internationalization and firm performance. Organization Science, 19(4), 623-646. doi:10.1287/orsc.1070.0341
https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1070.0341...
and Hashai et al. (2018)Hashai, N., Kafouros, M., & Buckley, P. J. (2018) The performance implications of speed, regularity, and duration in alliance portfolio expansion. Journal of Management, 44(2), 707-731. mention the unavailability of appropriate instruments (which, at times, are marginally relevant), which makes it difficult to assess possible endogeneity. In addition, the wide use of lagged dependent variables does not guarantee the exogeneity of the regressors. Therefore, as indicated by Bruyaka and Durand (2012)Bruyaka, O., & Durand, R. (2012). Sell-off or shut-down? Alliance portfolio diversity and two types of high tech firms' exit. Strategic Organization, 10(1), 7-30. doi: 10.1177/1476127011432366
https://doi.org/10.1177/1476127011432366...
, the careful assessment of possible endogeneity problems should be a subject for future studies.

RESULTS AND DISCUSSION

Sample

Table 1 indicates that 10,180 companies (78.19%) did not develop APD and may have realized some weak or not important partnerships. The innovative companies that developed APD (which attributed high and medium importance to their developed partnership(s)) totaled 2,840. Therefore, the present study was conducted based on the levels of variation in the "total sample" (13,020 companies) and a "subsample" (2,840 companies).

Table 1
Number of observations by number of partner type, for companies that developed APD.

In Table 2, the percentage of sales from incrementally and radically innovative products reaches an average of 17% when all 13,020 observations are considered. The average number of people employed by the companies is 475; this variable exhibits a high standard deviation, which indicates a large dispersion in its values. The average of the APD variable is 0.047. This value can be explained as follows: in Table 2, this variable was based on the total sample (13,020 observations), including the 10,180 companies that did not attribute importance to their developed partnerships, which means they did not achieve APD.

Table 2
Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix

Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics, highlighting the differences between the total sample (all innovative firms) and the subsample (innovative firms that developed APD).

Table 3
Means and standard deviations of variables in the sample and subsample

Companies in the Brazilian industry seem to be incorporating the APD strategy. In 2008, the average number of types of partners was 2.73 (0.195 x 14) and, in 2011, this average increased to 3.30 (0.236 x 14). The average percentage of sales of innovative products was 19.84% in 2008, increasing to 21.30% in 2011. The average number of employees is higher in the subsample, which indicates that companies that develop APD tend to be larger.

Regressions

In Table 4, model 1 includes only the main variables for the empirical model. In model 2, the independent variable APD squared is added. Model 3 includes the interaction of APD and the SCA variable, reflecting the moderating function of the latter variable. In Model 4, the interaction APD and the RDCA variable is inserted, reflecting the moderating function of the latter variable. Model 5 incorporates the last interaction term, of the moderating variables SCA and RDCA, reflecting the combined effect of these variables on the dependent variable. Finally, model 6 includes all the variables of the empirical model proposed above.

Table 4
Tobit regressions – Dependent variable: TOTAL_IN

In model 1, APD has a positive and statistically significant relationship with innovative performance. However, as APD increases, the benefits from this strategy do not outweigh the costs involved. This is shown by the significantly negative sign of the quadratic term of APD in model 2. This result confirms the inverted U-shaped relationship between APD and innovative performance, in line with hypothesis 1. The six estimated Tobit models confirm the signs of the relationships stated in hypothesis 1, as well as show their high degree of statistical significance.

Based on model 4, hypothesis 2 is also confirmed. The curvilinear relationship between APD and the firm's innovative performance is smoothed (flattened) if the firm invests in RDCA. The moderation of RDCA is indicated by the positive sign of the interaction between this variable and the quadratic term of APD. Model 6 also confirms this relationship.

Model 3 shows a significantly positive relationship between the quadratic term of APD and SCA. This finding supports hypothesis 3, confirming that, in the presence of SCA, the curvilinear relationship between APD and innovative performance is softened (flattened). This relationship can also be seen in model 6.

Hypothesis 4 was not confirmed. The positive sign of the relationship between the moderating variables SCA and RDCA was expected. In model 6, the interaction term between these two variables significantly negative. This result contradicts complementarity and substitutability between these two variables. The curvilinear relationship and the moderating effects are shown in Graphs 1 and 2.

Graphs 1 and 2
Impact of RDCA and SCA on the (APD X Innovative performance) relationship

Similar to the Tobit models, six OLS (Ordinary Least Squares) models were also fit, to test the stability of the results (Table 5). The results for the relationships between the variables of interest remained stable. Hypotheses 1, 2, and 3 were also confirmed by the OLS models. The only exception was the interaction term of the moderating variables RDCA x SCA (hypothesis 4), which lost statistical significance in the complete model (model 6).

Table 5
OLS regressions - Dependent variable: TOTAL_IN

Discussion, implications, and limitations

The confirmation of hypothesis 1 indicates that companies in the Brazilian industry have been diversifying their alliance portfolios and have been benefiting from this strategy in terms of innovation. However, the industry faces the issue of APD costs neutralizing benefits after a certain point. On average, the number of partner types has increased from 2.73 in 2008 to 3.30 in 2011. Within the group that adhered to APD, the sales percentage corresponding to product innovations increased by almost two percentage points in the same period. According to Graphs 1 and 2, the inflection point of the curve indicates that five is the "ideal number" of different types of partners. The data suggest that there is still room for APD in the Brazilian industry, since 65% of the companies that adhered to APD developed up to two types of partners and 87.21% of all companies developed between one and four types. Thus, although companies in the Brazilian industry have been assimilating the cooperation strategy, they seem to be doing so cautiously.

The types of innovation that have impacted sales are "only process" and "product and process." "Product only" innovation has significantly decreased (IBGE, 2011Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística. (2011). Rio de Janeiro, Brasil: IBGE-PINTEC - Pesquisa de Inovação - triênios 2006-2008 e 2009-2011.). Thus, the general classification of the Brazilian industry as exhibiting imitation and incremental innovation seems to be a coherent conclusion (Carvalho & Avellar, 2015Carvalho, L., & Avellar, A. P. M. (2015). Comportamento inovativo da indústria brasileira: Uma análise do perfil das empresas com base na Pintec. VIII Congresso do Instituto Franco-Brasileiro de Administração de Empresas (IFBAE), Gramado, RS.; Cavalcante & Negri, 2011Cavalcante, L. R., & Negri, F. De. (2011). Trajetória recente dos indicadores de inovação no Brasil (Texto para Discussão, n. 1.659). Brasília, DF: IPEA.; Kannebley, Porto, & Pazello, 2004Kannebley, S., Júnior, Porto, G. S., & Pazello, E. T. (2004). Inovação na indústria brasileira : Uma análise exploratória a partir da Pintec. Revista Brasileira de Inovação, 3(1), 87-128. doi: 10.20396/rbi.v3i1.8648893
https://doi.org/10.20396/rbi.v3i1.864889...
; Mendes, Lopes, & Gomes, 2012Mendes, C. S., Lopes, L. S., & Gomes, A. P. (2012). Eficiência dos dispêndios em inovação nas indústrias de transformação do Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Inovação, 11(1), 193-218. doi: 10.20396/rbi.v11i1.8649031
https://doi.org/10.20396/rbi.v11i1.86490...
).

Although APD is spreading, companies-and their partners-have not been able to make the Brazilian innovation environment more dynamic with disruptive innovations. The emphasis on suppliers and customers/consumers as being the most and second-most important reinforces incremental and process innovation (Leeuw et al., 2014Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.1...
; Sobrero & Roberts, 2002Sobrero, M., & Roberts, E. B. (2002). Strategic management of supplier-manufacturer relations in new product development. Research Policy, 31(1), 159-182. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00157-8
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00...
). It can also be considered that this behavior reflects companies' accommodation to the needs of the domestic market. This possibility helps one understand why the significantly negative coefficient of the export control variable in the 6 regression models. The low percentage of exporting companies (5%) and of companies with foreign capital (13%) in the sample and the sharp drop in the percentage of companies belonging to the largest business group-25% to 17%-reinforce this perception.

Regarding hypothesis 2, when comparing innovative companies with innovators that developed APD, the latter's investments in RDCA are significantly (three times) higher than those of the former. This finding explains the stability of the results related to the moderating effect of RDCA shown by the regression models. However, when analyzing the estimated standard deviations, this variable exhibited high variation among the companies that adhered to APD, suggesting that this strategy still lacks maturity and consistency.

CA, together with the intellectual property regime and the dominant product paradigm, form part of the theoretical scenario supported by hypothesis 3. According to Teece (1986)Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
, these are the elements that define who benefits from an innovation: the innovative firm or the imitating firm. Based on the current consideration of the Brazilian industry as an imitator, this study suggests that companies invest in CA not only to compete internally, offering good market access structures, but also to become attractive partners for innovative companies. Thus, in a competitive environment where the ownership regime is not strong, a firm with a good market-access structure (production, distribution, and marketing) can capture the profits of an innovation via cooperation or imitation, even if entering the market late.

Not confirming the fourth hypothesis reinforces the substitutability relationship between RDCA and SCA. Further analyzing this relationship, this study corroborates the contributions of Lane and Lubatkin (1998)Lane, P. J., & Lubatkin, M. (1998). Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic Management Journal, 19(5), 461-477. doi:10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199805)19:5<461::AID-SMJ953>3.3.CO;2-C
https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(...
and Teece (1986)Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
. At the beginning of the firm's value chain, the firm's R&D area involves skills and competencies linked to access to knowledge or technologies, with the firm seeking new combinations of ideas and establishing the "dominant product paradigm" (Teece, 1986Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)900...
). At the end of the firm's value chain, SCA provide skills and competencies to access the market and to establish efficient production and marketing structures, which is the company's "dominant logic" (Lane & Lubatkin, 1998Lane, P. J., & Lubatkin, M. (1998). Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic Management Journal, 19(5), 461-477. doi:10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199805)19:5<461::AID-SMJ953>3.3.CO;2-C
https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(...
).

In this context, how can it be guaranteed that a given firm aligns the "dominant product paradigm" with the "dominant logic"? Non-alignment between these two theoretical elements can bring about the Schumpeterian occurrence of "creative destruction," where the dominant product paradigm can destroy the competencies established at the end of the firm's value chain, and the latter can discourage the search for the former. To place this discussion in the context of APD, one can see that these efforts, at the beginning and at the end of the chain, are developed through alliances with external partners.

Another possible explanation comes from Andrevsky et al. (2016)Andrevsky, G., Brass, D. J., & Ferrier, W. J. (2016) Alliance portfolio configurations and competitive action frequency. Journal of Management, 42(4), 811-837. doi: 10.1177/0149206313498901
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206313498901...
, who tested and proved that portfolio configuration disproportionately influences a firm's strategic competitive actions (product development) and tactical competitive actions (commercialization). This possible explanation also corroborates the approach of Milagres et al. (2017)Milagres, R., Rezende, O., & Silva, S. A. G. (2017). Papel e posição do departamento de alianças: Caso Embrapa. Revista de Administração Pública, 51(3), 431-450 doi:10.1590/0034-7612160046
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612160046...
, who emphasized the importance of the functions and relationships developed between the area that manages alliances and other areas of the organization.

The forces that exist in this type of context exert "inertial pressures," because the individual who conducts the research may not be the same individual who decides whether the research will continue (Kapoor & Klueter, 2015Kapoor, R., & Klueter, T. (2015). Decoding the adaptability-rigidity puzzle: Evidence from pharmaceutical incumbents' pursuit of gene therapy and monoclonal antibodies. Academy of Management Journal, 58(4), 1180-1207. doi:10.5465/amj.2013.0430
https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2013.0430...
). In the specific context of this study, the lack of alignment between these pressures may explain the negative sign of the interaction term between RDCA and SCA. The "creative destruction" is not fully realized in the creation of new competencies or radical skills, since, on average, companies in the Brazilian industry innovate incrementally. In terms of APD, the importance of suppliers and customers may be causing this situation. Partnerships with universities/research institutes, only appearing in third place and at a much smaller proportion than the first two partnership types, also support this conclusion. However, even if these forces are not completely aligned, their individual effects on the relationship between APD and innovative performance were detected, which validates the theoretical/empirical model proposed here.

In general, based on Graphs 1 and 2, one can perceive the weak moderating effects stated in hypotheses 2 and 3, even though such effects were statistically significant. The weak "flattening" of the curve appears to reflect the Brazilian innovative environment. Corporate R&D initiatives still seem immature while SCA, to be more effective, may need an environment where greater legal certainty exists since these assets are included in categories of activities less subject to normative institutional controls. In other words, RDCA and SCA positively moderate an innovative result but this still needs to be consistently kept in mind. Finally, the weak flattening of the curve may reflect the substitutability between RDCA and SCA.

The contribution of this study to the theory of open innovation is that it identifies APD as a strategy that benefits a firm's performance. The present study also extends AC theory as it considers APD not as an element that has more than one dimension only in terms of skills and competencies but also in terms of a spatial dimension. Thus, AC, when used by a firm's other internal subunits, can be indirectly connected to the vision of the firm's knowledge and learning. From a managerial perspective, the importance of the firm's senior management performance is explicit, in terms of its emphasizing synergies and neutralizing conflicts that may emerge between the subunits that act like radars in the competitive environment, seeking useful alliances.

The limitations of this study relate to the sample's high heterogeneity, as well as the treatment of APD as a homogeneous strategy, that is, without considering, for example, the level of internationalization of this strategy. In addition, due to Pintec's data limitations, this study did not use a more effective approach for attributing causality between the variables, which require using panel data. Other limitations related to the Pintec database, which may have impacted the sample, involve the specificities of the innovative organizational environment. In the case of the variable measuring a firm's R&D efforts-which was a sample selection criterion-the study's scope indicated the option of using this variable as a moderating variable (level of investments and external environment) and as a control variable (level of investments and internal environment). This option proved to be the best among other alternatives.

However, it is recognized that such limitations, either due to the database or the scope of the research, may have impacted the results. For instance, they may have caused the modest moderation effect of the curvilinear relationship captured by the figures, as well as the cases of marginal statistical significance, especially that of the SCA moderating variable.

Thus, there are opportunities for future research related to sample segmentation strategies, for example, using the criterion of technological intensity or a regional analysis. It is also possible to consider the insertion of variables specifically relevant to the relationships between the subunits of the firm, or the specific evaluation of the effects of joint ventures on innovative performance. Finally, innovative performance can be measured in ways that are less obvious than those normally found in the literature, such as the impacts of this performance on costs, market share, and also environmental issues.

REFERÊNCIAS

  • Andrevsky, G., Brass, D. J., & Ferrier, W. J. (2016) Alliance portfolio configurations and competitive action frequency. Journal of Management, 42(4), 811-837. doi: 10.1177/0149206313498901
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206313498901
  • Asgari, N., Singh, K., & Mitchell, W. (2017). Alliance portfolio reconfiguration following a technological discontinuity. Strategic Management Journal, 38, 1062-1081. doi: 10.1002/smj.2554
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2554
  • Baum, J. A. C.; Calabrese,T.; Silverman, B. S. (2000). Don't go it alone: alliance network composition and startups' performance in canadian biotechnology. Strategic Management Journal 21, 267-294. doi: 10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(200003)21:33.0.CO;2-8
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(200003)21:33.0.CO;2-8
  • Benner, M. J., & Tushman, M. L. (2003). Exploitation, exploration, and process management: The productivity dilemma revisited. Academy of Management Review, 28(2), 238-256. doi: 10.2307/30040711
    » https://doi.org/10.2307/30040711
  • Berchicci, L. (2013). Towards an open R&D system: Internal R&D investment, external knowledge acquisition and innovative performance. Research Policy, 42(1), 117-127. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2012.04.017
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.04.017
  • Bogers, M., Burcharth, A., & Chesbrough, H. (2019). Open innovation in Brazil: Exploring opportunities and challenges. International Journal of Innovation, 7(2), 178-191. doi: 10.5585/iji.v7i2.417.2318-9975
    » https://doi.org/10.5585/iji.v7i2.417.2318-9975
  • Bruyaka, O., & Durand, R. (2012). Sell-off or shut-down? Alliance portfolio diversity and two types of high tech firms' exit. Strategic Organization, 10(1), 7-30. doi: 10.1177/1476127011432366
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/1476127011432366
  • Caloghirou, Y., Kastelli, I., & Tsakanikas, A. (2004). Internal capabilities and external knowledge sources: Complements or substitutes for innovative performance? Technovation, 24(1), 29-39. doi: 10.1016/S0166-4972(02)00051-2
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/S0166-4972(02)00051-2
  • Carvalho, L., & Avellar, A. P. M. (2015). Comportamento inovativo da indústria brasileira: Uma análise do perfil das empresas com base na Pintec. VIII Congresso do Instituto Franco-Brasileiro de Administração de Empresas (IFBAE), Gramado, RS.
  • Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2002). R&D cooperation and spillovers: Some empirical evidence from Belgium. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1169-1184. doi: 10.1257/00028280260344704
    » https://doi.org/10.1257/00028280260344704
  • Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in innovation strategy: Internal R&D and external knowledge acquisition. Management Science, 52(1), 68-82. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470
    » https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1050.0470
  • Cavalcante, L. R., & Negri, F. De. (2011). Trajetória recente dos indicadores de inovação no Brasil (Texto para Discussão, n. 1.659). Brasília, DF: IPEA.
  • Ceccagnoli, M., Higgins, M. J., & Palermo, V. (2014). Behind the scenes: Sources of complementarity in R&D. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 23(1), 125-148. doi:10.1111/jems.12048
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12048
  • Chesbrough, H. W. (2003). Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from technology(Vol. 2.006). Boston, USA: Harvard Business School Press. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8691.2008.00502.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8691.2008.00502.x
  • Chesbrough, H. W. (2006). Open business models: How to thrive in the new innovation landscape. Boston, USA: Harvard Business Review Press.
  • Chiu, Y. C., Lai, H. C., Lee, T. Y., & Liaw, Y. C. (2008). Technological diversification, complementary assets, and performance. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 75(6), 875-892. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2007.07.003
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2007.07.003
  • Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(3), 128-152. doi:10.1177/0149206310369939
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310369939
  • Dibiaggio, L., Nasiriyar, M., & Nesta, L. (2014). Substitutability and complementarity of technological knowledge and the inventive performance of semiconductor companies. Research Policy, 43(9), 1582-1593. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2014.04.001
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2014.04.001
  • Duysters, G., & Lokshin, B. (2011). Determinants of alliance portfolio complexity and its effect on innovative performance of companies. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 28(4), 570-585. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2011.00824.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2011.00824.x
  • Escribano, A., Fosfuri, A., & Tribó, J. A. (2009). Managing external knowledge flows: The moderating role of absorptive capacity. Research Policy, 38(1), 96-105. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2008.10.022
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2008.10.022
  • Faems, D., Visser, M. De, Andries, P., & Looy, B. Van. (2010). Technology alliance portfolios and financial performance: Value-enhancing and cost-increasing effects of open innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27(6), 785-796. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00752.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00752.x
  • Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 97 doi:10.1198/jasa.2002.s458
    » https://doi.org/10.1198/jasa.2002.s458
  • Gujarati, D. N., & Porter, D. C. (2011). Econometria básica Porto Alegre, Brasil: Amgh Editora. doi:10.1126/science.1186874
    » https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1186874
  • Hagedoorn, J., & Wang, N. (2012). Is there complementarity or substitutability between internal and external R&D strategies? Research Policy, 41(6), 1072-1083. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2012.02.012
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.02.012
  • Hashai, N., Kafouros, M., & Buckley, P. J. (2018) The performance implications of speed, regularity, and duration in alliance portfolio expansion. Journal of Management, 44(2), 707-731.
  • Hess, A. M., & Rothaermel, F. T. (2011). When are assets complementary? Star scientists, strategic alliances, and innovation in the pharmaceutical industry. Strategic Management Journal, 32(8), 895-909. doi:10.1002/smj.916
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.916
  • Huizingh, E. K. R. E. (2011). Open innovation: State of the art and future perspectives. Technovation, 31(1), 2-9. doi:10.1016/j.technovation.2010.10.002
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2010.10.002
  • Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística. (2011). Rio de Janeiro, Brasil: IBGE-PINTEC - Pesquisa de Inovação - triênios 2006-2008 e 2009-2011.
  • Jiang, R. J., Tao, Q. T., & Santoro, M. D. (2010). Research notes and commentaries alliance portfolio diversity and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 31, 1136-1144. doi:10.1002/smj.869
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.869
  • Jong, J. P. J. De, & Freel, M. (2010). Absorptive capacity and the reach of collaboration in high technology small firms. Research Policy, 39(1), 47-54. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2009.10.003
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2009.10.003
  • Kale, P., & Singh, H. (2009). Managing strategic alliances: What do we know now, and where do we go from here? Academy of Management Perspectives, 23(3), 45-62. doi:10.5465/AMP.2009.43479263
    » https://doi.org/10.5465/AMP.2009.43479263
  • Kannebley, S., Júnior, Porto, G. S., & Pazello, E. T. (2004). Inovação na indústria brasileira : Uma análise exploratória a partir da Pintec. Revista Brasileira de Inovação, 3(1), 87-128. doi: 10.20396/rbi.v3i1.8648893
    » https://doi.org/10.20396/rbi.v3i1.8648893
  • Kapoor, R., & Klueter, T. (2015). Decoding the adaptability-rigidity puzzle: Evidence from pharmaceutical incumbents' pursuit of gene therapy and monoclonal antibodies. Academy of Management Journal, 58(4), 1180-1207. doi:10.5465/amj.2013.0430
    » https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2013.0430
  • Katila, R. (2002). New product search over time: Past ideas in their prime? Academy of Management Journal, 45(5), 995-1010. doi: 10.2307/3069326
    » https://doi.org/10.2307/3069326
  • Kim, J. W., & Higgins, M. C. (2007). Where do alliances come from?. The effects of upper echelons on alliance formation. Research Policy, 36(4), 499-514. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2007.02.017
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2007.02.017
  • Lane, P. J., & Lubatkin, M. (1998). Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic Management Journal, 19(5), 461-477. doi:10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199805)19:5<461::AID-SMJ953>3.3.CO;2-C
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199805)19:5<461::AID-SMJ953>3.3.CO;2-C
  • Laursen, K., & Salter, A. (2004). Searching high and low: What types of firms use universities as a source of innovation? Research Policy, 33(8), 1201-1215. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2004.07.004
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2004.07.004
  • Laursen, K., & Salter, A. (2006). Open for innovation: The role of openness in explaining innovation performance among U.K. manufacturing firms. Strategic Management Journal, 27(2), 131-150. doi:10.1002/smj.507
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.507
  • Laursen, K., & Salter, A. J. (2014). The paradox of openness: Appropriability, external search and collaboration. Research Policy, 43(5), 867-878. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2013.10.004
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2013.10.004
  • Lavie, D., & Miller, S. R. (2008). Alliance portfolio internationalization and firm performance. Organization Science, 19(4), 623-646. doi:10.1287/orsc.1070.0341
    » https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1070.0341
  • Lee, G. K. (2007). The significance of network resources in the race to enter emerging product markets: The convergence of telephony communications and computer networking, 1989-2001. Strategic Management Journal, 28, 17-37. doi:10.1002/smj.566
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.566
  • Leeuw, T. De, Lokshin, B., & Duysters, G. (2014). Returns to alliance portfolio diversity: The relative effects of partner diversity on firm's innovative performance and productivity. Journal of Business Research, 67(9), 1839-1849. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.12.005
  • March, J. G. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2(1), 71. doi:10.1287/orsc.2.1.71
    » https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2.1.71
  • Mendes, C. S., Lopes, L. S., & Gomes, A. P. (2012). Eficiência dos dispêndios em inovação nas indústrias de transformação do Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Inovação, 11(1), 193-218. doi: 10.20396/rbi.v11i1.8649031
    » https://doi.org/10.20396/rbi.v11i1.8649031
  • Milagres, R., Rezende, O., & Silva, S. A. G. (2017). Papel e posição do departamento de alianças: Caso Embrapa. Revista de Administração Pública, 51(3), 431-450 doi:10.1590/0034-7612160046
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612160046
  • Nelson, R., & Winter, S. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change Cambridge, USA: The Belknapp Press of Harvard University Press.
  • Oerlemans, L. A. G., Knoben, J., & Pretorius, M. W. (2013). Alliance portfolio diversity, radical and incremental innovation: The moderating role of technology management. Technovation, 33(6-7), 234-246. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2013.02.004
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2013.02.004
  • Oxley, J. (1997). Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: A transaction-cost approach. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 13(2), 387-409. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a023389
    » https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a023389
  • Rothaermel, F. T. (2001). Incumbent's advantage through exploiting complementary assets via interfirm cooperation. Strategic Management Journal, 22(6-7), 687-699. doi:10.1002/smj.180
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.180
  • Rothaermel, F. T., & Deeds, D. L. (2004). Exploration and exploitation alliances in biotechnology: A system of new product development. Strategic Management Journal, 25(3), 201-221. doi:10.1002/smj.376
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.376
  • Rothaermel, F. T., & Hill, C. W. L. (2005). Technological discontinuities and complementary assets: A longitudinal study of industry and firm performance. Organization Science, 16(1), 52-70. doi: 10.1287/orsc.1040.0100
    » https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1040.0100
  • Sobrero, M., & Roberts, E. B. (2002). Strategic management of supplier-manufacturer relations in new product development. Research Policy, 31(1), 159-182. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00157-8
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00157-8
  • Spithoven, A., & Teirlinck, P. (2015). Internal capabilities, network resources and appropriation mechanisms as determinants of R&D outsourcing. Research Policy, 44(3), 711-725. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2014.10.013
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2014.10.013
  • Srivastava, M. K., & Gnyawali, D. R. (2011). When do relational resources matter? Leveraging technological resources for breakthrough innovation. Academy of Management Journal, 54(4), 797-810. doi: 10.5465/AMJ.2011.64870140
    » https://doi.org/10.5465/AMJ.2011.64870140
  • Taylor, A., & Helfat, C. E. (2009). Organizational linkages for surviving technological change: Complementary assets, middle management, and ambidexterity. Organization Science, 20(4), 718-739. doi:10.1287/orsc.1090.0429
    » https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1090.0429
  • Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285-305. doi: 10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(86)90027-2
  • Tether, B. S. (2002). Who co-operates for innovation, and why: An empirical analysis. Research Policy, 31(6), 947-967. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00172-X
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00172-X
  • Trajtenberg, M., Henderson, R., & Jaffe, A. (1997). University versus corporate patents: A window on the basicness of invention. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 5(1), 19-50. doi: 10.1080/10438599700000006
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599700000006
  • Tsai, K. H., & Wang, J. C. (2008). External technology acquisition and firm performance: A longitudinal study. Journal of Business Venturing, 23(1), 91-112. doi:10.1016/j.jbusvent.2005.07.002
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2005.07.002
  • Vasudeva, G., & Anand, J. (2011). Unpacking absorptive capacity: A study of knowledge utilization from alliance portfolios. Academy of Management Journal, 54(3), 611-623. doi: 10.5465/amj.2011.61968108
    » https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2011.61968108
  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2011). Introdução à econometria: Uma abordagem moderna São Paulo: Cengage Learning.
  • Wu, B., Wan, Z., & Levinthal, D. A. (2014). Complementary assets as pipes and prisms: Innovation incentives and trajectory choices. Strategic Management Journal, 35(9), 1257-1278. doi:10.1002/smj.2159
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2159
  • Zahra, S. A., & George, G. (2002). Absorptive capacity: A review, reconceptualization, and extension. Academy of Management Review 17(2), 185-203. doi:10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995
    » https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.2002.6587995
  • Ziedonis, A. A. (2007). Real options in technology licensing real options in technology licensing. Management Science, 53(10), 1618-1633.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    06 Nov 2020
  • Date of issue
    Sep-Oct 2020

History

  • Received
    30 Sept 2019
  • Accepted
    01 Apr 2020
Fundação Getulio Vargas, Escola de Administração de Empresas de S.Paulo Av 9 de Julho, 2029, 01313-902 S. Paulo - SP Brasil, Tel.: (55 11) 3799-7999, Fax: (55 11) 3799-7871 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: rae@fgv.br