SPECIAL FEATURES
SMALL BUSINESS ATRAVÉS DO PANÓPTICO
Guanxi economics: Confucius meets Lenin, Keynes, and Schumpeter in contemporary China
Manfred NitschI; Frank DiebelII
IProfessor emeritus of political economy, Department of Economics and Business Administration and University Center Latin American Institute, Freie Universitaet Berlin. E-mail: manfred.nitsch@t-online.de
IIDoctoral student of sinology and economics, Freie Universitaet Berlin. E-mail: home@frankdiebel.de
"Espaço dedicado à divulgação de estudos e pesquisas sobre o conceito de small business: micro, pequenas e médias empresas (MPMEs); empreendedorismo; jovens empresários; acesso ao crédito; meios de pagamento; e responsabilidade social."
Coordenação: Deborah Moraes Zouain* * Coordenadores do Programa de Estudos Avançados em Pequenos Negócios, Empreendedorismo, Acesso ao Crédito e Meios de Pagamento (Small Business), da Escola Brasileira de Administração Pública e de Empresas da Fundação Getulio Vargas (Ebape/FGV). Endereço: Praia de Botafogo, 190, 5o andar CEP 22250-900, Rio de Janeiro, RJ, Brasil. E-mail: small@fgv.br.
Francisco Marcelo Barone* * Coordenadores do Programa de Estudos Avançados em Pequenos Negócios, Empreendedorismo, Acesso ao Crédito e Meios de Pagamento (Small Business), da Escola Brasileira de Administração Pública e de Empresas da Fundação Getulio Vargas (Ebape/FGV). Endereço: Praia de Botafogo, 190, 5o andar CEP 22250-900, Rio de Janeiro, RJ, Brasil. E-mail: small@fgv.br.
1. The challenge
The recent economic growth story of the People's Republic of China is not yet fully understood. Consequently, the amazing increase in national income over the past 25 years is still a matter of debate among economic theorists. Recent research has shed some light on the macro-economics of economic growth in China, concentrating on the export drive via an undervaluation of its currency (Priewe, 2005; Herr, 2002). In this paper, the micro-foundations of the Chinese growth model are analysed, much in the same vein as Priewe and Herr, namely within a comprehensive monetary theory of economic development, based on Schumpeter, Keynes, and the contemporary monetary Keynesians such as Hajo Riese, but adapted to the Confucian traditions and the contemporary Leninist party power structure in China.
The benefit of a monetary theory of development and underdevelopment in contrast to other theories of economic growth is that it does not take growth for granted but encompasses also stagnation and underdevelopment, emphasizing the social division of labour and, in particular, the institutional setup of the monetary sphere. Instead of referring to time-preference for future consumption, 'animal spirits', and mechanical incremental capital-output ratios, with secure private property rights, a rule of law, and the vector of real resources as the dominant budget constraint, as in neoclassical theory, money, in a very broad sense of the term, is considered here to be dominant in any contemporary economy, so that macro as well as micro financial issues become crucial variables. All the more, a phenomenon like spectacular growth in China, where many of the much-invoked 'preconditions' of development in a functioning capitalist market economy are conspicuously absent, presents a formidable challenge to economic theory-building, particularly for developing and transition countries. In the following section, the Schumpeter-Keynesian growth model is sketched out, with a view on whether and how it could be applied to contemporary China, whose basic economic structure is briefly characterized in section 3. In stark contrast to the transition path of Russia and other formerly socialist economies, a loss of coherence could be avoided due to the perseverance of the Communist Party. Finally, scenarios for future developments and some theoretical lessons learned conclude the article.
2. Schumpeter's accumulation model for monetary economies
As the main visualising instrument for explaining, step by step, the implicit growth model of Schumpeter's theory of economic development (1912-34), the balance sheets of the economic agents involved are used, which consist of stocks (not flows) with assets on the left hand side, and liabilities on the right, showing net wealth or equity as a balance. Our agents in focus are the entrepreneur (ER), the banker (BK), the wealth owner (WO), the employed worker or employee (LE), the unemployed labourer (LU), and the consumer (CO). The State (ST) is only the night-watchman and rule-setter. In the beginning, money is one of the assets in the portfolio of all the actors (figure 1), who use it as cash in spot markets so that its real, not its nominal value counts within the preference scale of the individuals.
When Milton Friedman's famous helicopter throws down the same amount of cash, and each individual gathers exactly the same amount which he or she1 1 Gender aspects are not being treated here so that the male version is used for both sexes, if not otherwise expressed. already is holding in their portfolios, prices rise and double, but nothing else happens with the real economy (Friedman, 1992, ch. 2). Economic growth is essentially an accumulation of real assets, financed out of the savings of the same or some other individual household or enterprise which, in turn, are determined by the time preference for future consumption.
In essence, this thinking is reflected not only in the more elaborate theories of monetarists with regard to monetary policies, but also in neoclassical growth theories where, on the national level, investment (I) is determined by the national savings rate (S), and if that is insufficient to finance an intended growth objective, the 'savings gap' has to be filled with foreign savings, namely a current account deficit (M - X), be it commercial debt, foreign direct investment, remittances, or official development assistance (ODA). This model has been attacked by Easterly as a 'ghost' (1999) haunting the international financial institutions and the economists worldwide (2002), because neither in theory nor in terms of econometrics, the basic relationships hold true. Investment is not added up from local and foreign savings (I = S + M - X), insinuating that exports are detrimental for investment and growth, but on the contrary, ever since Keynes, it is well established that savings and imports are leakages to demand, and investment is a rather autonomous variable. The formula which is, of course, always true ex post in every variant, has to be written the other way: To be interpreted ex ante as a residual, or better, an explanandum, namely resulting accumulation, macroeconomic saving depends on income generation through investment and exports: S = I + X - M. Thus I and X become the crucial variables for growth, not S and M. And leaving, for the time being, the export surplus on the current account of the balance of payments to the macroeconomics of Chinese development (Priewe, 2005; Herr, 2002), the microeconomics and the institutional setting of investment, not saving, will be in the centre of attention in the following.
The next step in monetary theory introduces financial assets and liabilities connecting surplus and deficit units, partly intermediated by banks and other financial intermediaries (figure 2). Still, the impression is created that enterprises, as deficit units, can only invest what surplus households and other wealth owners save so that the 'theory of finance' (McKinnon, 1973; Shaw, 1973) is compatible with both neoclassical and Keynesian schools of thought. The capital markets and financial intermediaries become decisive for financing investment, because enterprises are thus modelled as wholly dependent on equity and liability finance, whereas the entrepreneurial functions are delegated to managers, who are not necessarily entitled to profit-sharing, let alone to take all or the most part of the profit as the entrepreneur in the following model.
To explain economic development in a monetary economy, Schumpeter makes a fundamental discovery in 1911/12, which is still not yet fully recognized, but fits in very well with the monetary Keynesian approach: He focuses on the relationship between two main economic agents of any national monetary economy: the entrepreneur and the banker. In Schumpeter's theory of economic development, the entrepreneur does not depend on his own past savings nor on anybody else's foregoing of consumption, but on the credit which the banker is willing and able to hand out to him as a borrower for his investment. In his theory, the lending limit obviously is dependent on the trustworthiness of the entrepreneur as a person and of his project as an innovation to be pursued with profit. As long as the entrepreneur can convince the banker of his future-compliant innovative ideas, the banker will finance his investments. The main idea of this concept is that none of the economic agents saved before or concomitant to investment. No 'consumption renunciation first' is of any need. Instead, the credit is created ex nihilo (in the original German: "aus Nichts"; "from nothing", namely without savings): The banker puts his trust into the entrepreneurial ability and the willingness of the borrower to repay the loan. If we take a look at the balance sheets of both the banker and the entrepreneur (figure 3), we will find a mutual credit relation, namely a claim of the banker against the entrepreneur on the asset side of the bank's balance sheet and a sight deposit of the entrepreneur on its liabilities side.
In the next step the entrepreneur needs real assets for his entrepreneurial activities. He will have to buy those real assets from the wealth owner (WO). Their deal will be closed and the entrepreneur will receive the needed real assets from the wealth owner via the asset markets, and he will pay with a cheque on his sight deposit; the bank carries out a transfer from the account of the entrepreneur to the checking account of WO, provided that the banker is considered trustworthy. In WO's portfolio real assets are substituted by financial assets.
The same happens on the labour market, since the entrepreneur needs to combine real assets with human capital (LE) to carry out his entrepreneurial activities. ER can pay the price for the asset, the interest on the loan, and competitive wages, because he has an innovative project, for which, by the way, possession and control are important, not necessarily definite private property, which lends itself easily for speculation instead of productive projects.
In balance sheet terms, ER changes financial assets for real ones, and he hires LE giving the worker or employee a wage advance, confident that, in the future, he can sell the innovative product to the consumer CO (directly or through some intermediary, with or without consumer credit). So far the investment activity of the entrepreneur has been based solely upon financial liabilities and assets. Cash has not come into play yet. But in terms of asset preferences and management, the wealth owner might want to transfer part of his financial assets into cash instead of leaving it on his sight or savings account at the bank (figure 4). The same counts for the worker who might need cash to pay his purchases instead of writing out cheques. Since the central bank is the only institution in a national economy which is allowed to issue money (cash), the lending ceiling for the banker who finances entrepreneurial activities thus depends on the amount of discount credit supplied to him by the central bank.
Ever since Bagehot's famous Lombard street, of 1873 (Bagehot, 1999; Porcelluzzi, 2005), the central bank is modelled as a "lender of last resort" meaning that, in a functioning monetary economy, a run on banks is avoided by the central bank's "lending freely, at a penalty rate, against good collateral" so that solid, profitable banks are rescued from liquidity crises, albeit no over-indebted ones from insolvency. Again, trust comes into play, because the central banker has to trust the commercial banker not only when he asks for refinancing in such a crisis, but also in their day-to-day dealings. The open discount window enables banks to hold only modest liquid reserves; otherwise no efficient monetary economy would be viable. Thus, the crucial budget constraint on employment and investment is not the vector of real resources but the dominant financial sphere, guided by credit in its larger meaning, namely including trust and confidence beyond bookkeeping numbers.
This is the way money comes into existence in a monetary economy. The main point here to understand is that in monetary economies, money is not only a means of exchange on spot markets, but also, and primarily, a means of deferred payment between creditors and debtors. Furthermore, in our context it is highly important to stress the universality of money as the means for the final redemption from debt and for the acquisition of land, labour, and all the other tangible and non-tangible assets necessary for a successful enterprise.
To fully comprehend the main argument of this monetary theory of development and underdevelopment, it is highly important to make clear itssocial division of labour and how the various economic agents are modelled. In this Keynesian monetary theory of development and underdevelopment the Schumpeterian entrepreneur (in the original German: "Unternehmer") does not own real assets at all, but he is the only economic agent who has got innovative ideas for new combinations of the factors of production. Often misinterpreted, he does not risk his own real or financial assets, because he has none, but he has ideas and entrepreneurial talents, and, above all, he has the right to claim the residual, i.e., to make profit. The risk lies with the wealth owner and the banker. Only in the next round, when ER reinvests the profit, he has something to lose beyond his reputation.
The wealth owner is of crucial importance in our monetary economy. He is the owner of the real assets and from the second round on also of the financial assets. He may be what Schumpeter calls a "Wirt", that is an individual who uses his own resources in a traditional way, without major innovations in the neoclassical equilibrium and without any inherent need for credit! For him, money is first and foremost cash for purchases in spot markets so that the wirt can easily live with inflation, and Friedman's helicopter metaphor might quite aptly model him and his fellow wirte. In an uncertain world, real assets can be hedged against inflation and risk so that it may be totally reasonable to leave a substantial part of them idle. In the model, the wealth owner hasn't got the ability to figure out new combinations of the factors of production nor is he eager enough to push through innovative ideas. In principle, Schumpeter's wirt is not a victim, because he receives the market price for his assets. However, competition by the unternehmer's new products and his demand for factors of production can and will reduce the market opportunities of many of the traditional producers so that Schumpeter's famous "creative destruction" always comes into the picture in spite of the assumption of fair asset prices and competitive markets. The more so, when previously "idle" natural capital, not well husbanded or defended by any wirt, is drawn into commercial use and abuse.
Therefore, in order to create economic growth and development beyond what Marx would have called "simple reproduction", there is need for a secondary distribution of real assets and human capital in favour of the innovative and assertive entrepreneur who is capable of investing in a new and profitable production line. Not being the risk-taking financier, the Schumpeterian entrepreneur risks only his reputation when he fails to service his loan to the banker or the mortgage or dividend to the traditional wealth owner. It is the latter, not the consumer, who becomes the true sovereign of the monetary economy, because he remains with the right and the possibility not to give up his hold on the real assets. Thus his Keynesian liquidity preference is enhancing or blocking the road to employment and growth, depending on his trust in other members of society.
Since the lending bank would not be able to give any loan to any entrepreneur if the central bank were not in a position to issue money, the national central bank is an absolutely essential institution in monetary economies. This point needs to be emphasised, too: it is very important to understand that its discount credit to the banks, as well as its money issue, is also created ex nihilo, and that they are solely based on the trustful relationship with the bankers and with the public, which must be willing to hold cash from that central bank, and not other ones, in its portfolio. It is hard to find any 'fundamentals' for those fragile credit chains and money issues in the real economy. This tends to become rather obvious in the case of crises, i.e., when the whole financial building crashes and the motor runs in the rear gear. In this sense, this monetary growth theory is also a theory of underdevelopment, since the concept of investment credit being created ex nihilo (from nothing) allows and indeed suggests the possibility of a credit crunch throwing the economy in nihil (into nothing).
In order to understand the fundamental character of this rather theoretical reasoning about monetary affairs, not only the big leaps from and to nothing are to be considered, but also the marginal steps: Schumpeter's unternehmer normally becomes a wirt when his pioneer profit erodes with competition, and his charismatic entrepreneurial spirit gives way to complacency, routine, and succession. The banker can become a wirt, too, in the sense that he sticks to financing going concerns, but no innovative investment. This leads us to two conclusions:
in a monetary economy, there is a need for securing normal ('equilibrium') economic life institutionally for the wirte, including their need for financial services by the banker, and that their life is precarious, too, because it could be stifled by a credit crunch, even though it would not be totally suffocated, since wirte use their own resources primarily, and do not rely on credit for their survival;
in order to grow beyond simple reproduction, i.e., a 100% replication of the previous year's gross domestic product, a secondary distribution of capital from the wirte to the unternehmer is essential, and it is here where the social division of labour between entrepreneur, intermediary and status-quo wealth owner on a total as well as on an incremental level and scale comes into play.
A final ingredient of the social formation under debate is the religious touch pervading the whole of society. Confidence stems from the Latin word fides belief or faith, which draws our attention to the belief system, religion or ethical superstructure, weltanschauung or cosmological order overarching the trust relations between the individual agents, and legitimising private property, profit-seeking, subtle and stringent control measures, as well as all kinds of sanctions when the rules are broken. For the capitalist monetary economy, another classical German text from the pre-World War I period comes to mind: Max Weber's Protestant ethics and the spirit of capitalism of 1905 ( "Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus), where the religious and ethical foundations of modern capitalism are sought in Calvinism and its puritan offspring. The restraint on consumption (cis-mundane asceticism "diesseitige Askese" in Weber's term), the dedication to work as a divine 'vocation' by the bourgeois (entrepreneur, top manager, and wealth owner in our terminology), and his accumulative and profit-seeking behaviour are identified as outcomes from specific religious roots and attitudes so that a certain normative varnish is spread over the whole institutional setup protecting it against revolt, revolution, and all kinds of violence.
The question now to be answered is, whether and how Schumpeter's and Weber's pre-World War I, rather Austrian and German world, with traditional in this case aristocratic wealth owners, fin-de-siècle entrepreneurs, fundamental technical innovations such as automobiles and electrical equipment, functioning banks, as well as workable asset and labour markets, and a secularised and generalised protestant ethic even in predominantly catholic regions of Europe, can be compared to contemporary China with its completely different cultural tradition, economic order, and politico-institutional regime.
3. The Chinese way
In the Chinese case, any highly important trustful relationship between the economic agents of the national economy is basically a matter of informal social relationships (). According to Luo Yadong, from the University of Miami, the term
refers to the concept of drawing on connections () in order to secure favors () in personal relations. It forms an intricate, pervasive relational network which the Chinese cultivate energetically, subtly, and imaginatively. It contains implicit mutual obligations, assurances, and understanding, and governs Chinese attitudes toward long-term social and business relationships. Broadly, means interpersonal linkages with the implication of continued exchange of favors.
(Luo, 2000:2)
This concept differs from western networking behaviour, especially in terms of its pervasive application among the people throughout Chinese society, consciously or subconsciously, based on its cultural Confucian origin. Indeed, is a particularly important matter of informal relational contracts between people that somehow feel closely related to each other. In this sense is a reciprocal social concept that mainly focuses on mutual emotions () between two or more individuals who, while cultivating their friendship, yet seek personal benefit. In order to understand this concept more precisely, four main terms that refer to in a larger sense have to be pointed out: social relationships (), emotions (), favours (), and face ().
The first expression () has a variety of meanings: concern, affect, matter, relation, relationship, and backdoor connections. For instance, one may translate the phrase () into: it doesn't matter, it isn't of (my) concern, it doesn't affect (me). However, the phrase definitely has the meaning of to draw on connections, which means that someone uses one's own connections to secure favours for himself or somebody else. Combining both meanings, it becomes clear that there is both an emotional and a social concept lying behind this term. indeed affects emotionally trustful interpersonal relations: No affection, no favours.
The second term () refers to the affected feeling involved in . The more is involved, the closer is the reciprocal personal relationship among individuals. The closer the , the more reliable it is for mutual material or political favours. One establishes through gift giving, eating together, coming and going, and social interaction (). Important to notice: does exist in both hierarchical and non-hierarchical settings. While it becomes respect () from a subordinate point of view, it becomes taking care () and trust () from a superior point of view. Among equals it either becomes friendship () or even love () (Kipnis, 1997:157).
The third term () is often translated into either humaneness, human feeling, relationship, gift, present, or favour. Like , this term refers to emotions as well. However, in the context of a social relationship, rénqíng especially points out that any individual who has human feelings () has involvement and trustful connections, too. Rénqíng actually enables any individual to distribute or secure favours on a reciprocal basis.
The last expression () is usually translated into face (literally and figuratively), reputation, prestige, and again feeling or sensibility. Someone who has face () has the ability to secure favours, too.
Since we have learned that every growing economy needs some sort of institutionalised intermediation between those who own the real assets in the status quo ante, and the entrepreneurs who figure out new combinations of the factors of production, we need to understand how the intermediation works in the special case of the People's Republic of China with its Leninist party and state, where collective (not private) ownership of the means of production has been a cornerstone of the socialist economic order. For the last three decades, public ownership has remained dominant, but thousands or millions of private enterprises have sprung up. However, banking has only very recently and very cautiously been transformed into something similar to capitalist commercial finance, asset markets have not yet been developed to a major degree, nor are labour markets what they are supposed to be in the Schumpeter model. The main question therefore is: how does the Chinese entrepreneur get the real assets from the Chinese wealth owner, and how does the underemployed human capital get employed? In the absence of capital markets and commercial banks, another distributor of resources has to be looked for.
The Taiwanese psychologist Huang Guangguo divides Chinese society into distributors of resources () on one hand and seekers of resources () on the other. First, before asking for favours, the seeker of resources needs to gain face () by social interaction ( ). Once the seeker of resources has face (), he is able to draw on connections ( ). Following Confucian rénqíng principles () the distributor of resources will then estimate his own benefit, considering the closeness of the relationship between himself and the seeker, thus calculating how much emotion ( ) actually is involved. Afterwards, the distributor decides whether or not to grant the favour ().
Notice, it is really important to understand that the distributor might withdraw an earlier favour. If the distributor fails to meet the requests of the seeker, the latter loses face (). However, if the distributor decides to allocate favours to the seeker, the latter, in fact, receives rénqíng () from the first. This is the way how both economic agents reinforce their relationship (: reinforce face). Obviously, the relationship between the seeker and the distributor in this Confucian "rénqíng-miànzi-model" (Guangguo, 1988), which describes the microeconomic foundation of the Chinese economy, comes close to the relationship between the Schumpeterian entrepreneur and his banker, and their mutual credit. This is especially true, because normally in China a given favour is, analogous to the bank credit, interest-bearing to the distributor's advantage (Yang, 1994:143-144).
The entrepreneur can be taken for granted, once private appropriation of profits has been allowed in China, and the potential for innovation, too, since the people's communes and enterprises of the state socialist era certainly left much to be desired in terms of the development of productive forces and modern technology. But where does one find Schumpeter's banker or, in terms of the already explained Chinese social relations, the distributor of resources? How are traditional wealth owners involved in this game of modern economic development? And what kind of cosmic order is prevalent in the superstructure of society?
Before looking for the equivalent to Schumpeter's banker, the real existing Chinese banks deserve some attention. Especially during the initial reform period, the banking system used to be set up like a traditional communist monobank system, subject to orders from planning officials and other authorities. Financial intermediation barely existed, and the investment of township or village enterprises was financed on command from above, and not subjected to serious evaluation by the bank. Even though the single bank system (People's Bank of China PBoC) had a few branches, which had to fulfil special tasks, it solely had to implement the central credit plan that was made up by the State Council and the Ministry of Finance.
Under these circumstances, neither the traditional wealth owner nor the banker could provide the entrepreneur with the necessary means of production, manpower, access to markets, and all the sorts of permits and complementary infrastructure and logistic requirements one needs for opening and running a modern business anywhere, let alone in a socialist country. Various kinds of power beyond the market are always needed and the clue to the Chinese power structure is the Communist Party of China (CCP), which has run the country since the civil war and the foundation of the People's Republic of China in 1949.
The CCP is a party in the Leninist tradition, which means that it considers itself and its members as a 'vanguard' in the sense of a hierarchical organisation structured by the principle of 'democratic centralism', leading the country into a bright future and knowing better than ordinary people what is right and what is wrong, in all dimensions of life. The resulting 'vanguard mode of production' (Lebowitz, 2000) is characterized by a strong corporate identity of the clergylike party, which is, in fact, the only institution that guarantees the degree of cohesion or coherence necessary in every society. Cohesion, in turn, requires universal power and means of intervention. Contrary to a capitalist market economy where "le monde va de lui-même" ("the world runs by itself"), as the famous dictum says, the vanguard leadership of communist parties in socialist countries requires deliberate decision-making and coordination on every level and between the levels of power, when the comprehensive mission is to be accomplished or at least not completely failed. Since no "invisible hand" (Adam Smith) can be conjured in an economy with administered prices and no asset markets, personal relations based on individual responsibility and visibility have to secure coherence in day-to-day affairs, as well as in the cosmic order stemming the forces of chaos in the superstructure of society. Thus mutual confidence or trust between persons is not something which is or might be somewhat more important than in a market economy, but it has a markedly different, pivotal, essential place in the working of the economic system so that the terms ' economy', for the recently developed mode of production in Mainland China, and ' economics', for the theoretical approach to come to analytical grips with those phenomena in the real world, are suggested here.
Analogous to the credit-deposit relation created ex nihilo between the entrepreneur and the banker in Schumpeter's world, the Chinese Communist Party secretary (PS) enables the entrepreneur by command ex nihilo to get hold of the resources, manpower and permits he needs for an innovative investment, when both of them trust each other and when they are confident that the enterprise will yield a profit, which is appropriated by ER, but somehow 'shared' by the PS, be it in monetary form, or as an enhancement of his power base with regard to the control over resources or of his reputation so that he can climb the ladder within the party and/or the state bureaucracies.
There were about 700 thousand party secretaries among approximately 60 million Chinese Communist Party members at the end of the 20th century, when party secretaries were, and still are heading the party cells () on each level and within each compartment of the state apparatus, the public utilities and generally also within the production units and housing complexes. The local party secretary, who heads the assembly of secretaries from the different local administrative and productive units, is so powerful, especially in the countryside, that he is often referred to or even addressed by his local constituents as local emperor (), not because of his formally high position within the structure of the party hierarchy, but because of the fact that he actually rules a large number of people in a certain area a village, a county, or a district (Wibowo, 2000:4). Like everywhere else in the world, on every level, the state in China is compartmentalized into ministries and similar agencies with specific functions which are headed by a government as the Executive Power. Without functioning markets, media, and legislatures, and without a central bank, neither the orientation of day-to-day decisions nor the securing of coherence in long-run policies can be expected from this conglomerate of partial bureaucracies or from its chief of government. It is the Leninist party which holds society together in the name of the people and its future destiny in Lebowitz' lucid term a "vanguard mode of production" (2000).
Command ex nihilo works as follows (figure 5). In a legal framework consisting of a rather conventional state structure, a vanguard party, a monobank system ruled by the central credit plan, and finally a local system of operating village enterprises and similar de facto wealth owners of the formally 'nationalized' real assets, the local Communist Party secretary is able to order the local to hand out the requested real assets to the local Schumpeterian entrepreneur. The same happens on the local labour market. Underemployed labour from the local work units will be instructed by the PS in power to start working for the local entrepreneur. Finally, the local representatives of the state bureaucracies are ordered to issue the necessary licences and permits and to provide the infrastructure and logistics. This command structure only works because the leading cadres to whom the orders are directed are generally also -related party members, i.e., comrades, whose promotion in business, administration and politics depends upon obedience to their superiors and good relations with their peers, and because there is, or at least should be, always some kind of 'consideration' (quid pro quo) for the withdrawal of resources. Throughout the People's Republic of China, the party secretary is the commander of the economy so that every citizen of Leninist-ruled China relies and depends on the resource allocation power of the Communist Party and its secretaries. However, it is important to understand that the resource distribution by the local party secretary's 'command' is based not only upon authoritarian power, but also upon a trustful relationship between the local and the administrative state officials concerned on one side, and the entrepreneur on the other, who is now in a debtor's position against the PS, while the latter is in a debtor's position against the local system, which, in turn, has to respond to the claims of its members and creditors. In this sense, the party secretary substitutes the financial intermediation of the capitalist system in a rather efficient way, providing coherence to an otherwise chaotic economy, while the Chinese banking system of the monetary economy is still on its path to gradual capitalist development.
Let us now look at the wealth owners (WO). In communist Chinese society, the central state as the representative of the 'people' is the formal owner, but the decisions about resource use are decentralized, the state units as parts of the Chinese politico-administrative system being in fact what one can call owners of the natural resources and the other real assets in the People's Republic of China. On the local level, the state was formerly divided into communes and brigades running commune and brigade enterprises, whose production teams () were in charge of using farm land, factories, manpower, and natural resources. During the initial period of the reforms, the smaller commune and brigade units where renamed township and village enterprises. In any case, different from Schumpeter's Austrian background, wealth owners were not individual persons but collectives in different legal forms. When trust as an exclusively human trait is supposed to be as important as assumed and explained so far, the modelling of the individuals behind those collectives becomes indispensable. Since the claims of those persons are highly important when it comes to a comprehensive understanding of 'development' in all its dimensions, those owners and claimants are abbreviated as 'other creditors' (OC) in the following, whereby it should become clear that the collective wealth owners are also indirect 'creditors' of the new entrepreneurs, and that those collectives are themselves, like banks and/or their substitute the PS, institutional intermediaries, subject to their managers, members/owners and creditors (figure 6)
As already hinted, our PS should not be misunderstood as being only a single individual person. We should rather consider the "assembly" of party secretaries on each level as the decisive nucleus of the command structure, where one party secretary might be in charge of the rather traditional township and village enterprise controlling the asset in question, another one or more are located within the 'regulating' state authorities involved, and another one in the township and village economic commission. Those informal and rather flexible assemblies are often called small leading groups () that are set up spontaneously by party secretaries on each level of the party state (Shirk, 1992:64-65). However, as Jean C. Oi has observed, the lower down the hierarchy the more a single party secretary might get involved in direct entrepreneurial activities, running even the innovative company, and chairing the board of directors of the local economic committee, or being in charge of other local political duties.
The lower down the hierarchy, the more intimately cadres are involved. Most visible is the village party secretary, who can be found personally intervening in the economic decision making of the village's enterprises, often chairing the board of directors of the village enterprise management committee.
(Oi, 1999:102)
Since the resources of society are formally nationalized, but no national institution is really in charge, the local assembly of party secretaries turns out to be the real and actual informal owner of the real assets, and the same assembly of party secretaries has also access to all the other factors of production and to the regulating agencies, because party secretaries are at the head of the (work and administrative unit) system, too. Being in a position not only to redistribute and reallocate resources, they actually are also able to initiate new and innovative production lines themselves within the enterprises, and there are instances of successful modernization of those contemporary Chinese wirte within the public sphere (Lau, 2006).
However, the description of those endeavours shows that the processes are slow and very laborious, and that rather heroic personalities and favourable circumstances are necessary for achieving significant economic growth, whereas the transition of resources from a public, collective (= de facto no-owner) wirt to a private unternehmer, with the PS as intermediary substituting Schumpeter's bankier, seems to be the dynamic prime solution to the Chinese growth puzzle, because it provides a powerful incentive for the PS and his fellow party members to transfer public to private ownership efficiently, and to benefit personally from that transfer, either in money or reputation or sociopolitical terms. This view makes it highly probable that the big boom will be over, once there is 'nothing left to steal' in the sense of no underemployed public resources left to be privatised. After that stage, the ER can only get relatively idle resources from other private owners, who always have the sovereign option to hold them back and hoard, and to continue their going concern or to speculate on further asset price increases. Still, the history of authoritarian political regimes with capitalist economies shows that private property must not always be an insurmountable hindrance for heavy state dirigisme.
In the transformation phase, the local assembly of Communist Party secretaries has not only got access to every specialized agency of the state, and it is not only in charge of the reallocation of property rights on real assets, but it is also responsible for taking care () of the needs of each member of society, namely the OCs, often the victims of change (see figure 6). During the reform process, the Communist Party secretary has been and increasingly becomes an economic agent, but, in the first place, he has still remained a political institution. Consequently, our PS is not only accountable to the shareholders of the innovative economic activities of the Schumpeterian entrepreneur, but he is also in charge of the whole infrastructure of the local system, the employment of its members in the local enterprises which are still under public control, and the social security of the non-active members of society.
For instance, when the local district PS decides that a traditionally managed pasture is transferred to an ER who promises to establish an apple plantation and an apple juice factory at that site, one party secretary is supposed to take care of the children playing there so that they get a place in the local kindergarten, another one is to provide a place for the shepherd in the local retirement centre, a third one is held responsible for the children and the elder relatives of the woman who is to work fulltime in that factory, and a fourth one has to be compensated for the wool and meat of the sheep which had been used by 'his' economic unit. The permit-issuing institutions, from the local fire department to the environmental and labour, construction and city planning agencies, are also, up to a certain degree, under his control. Since there is only one first PS responsible for every village, township or county, the members, employees, pensioners and/or just citizens, users and beneficiaries of the state agencies and enterprise are at his mercy as 'other creditors (OC)' (see figure 6). Like always in credit relations, the dominance is a question not only of who is in which chair, but also of who is more dependent on the compliance of the other. As a rule, the comrade party secretaries are urged to take care () of the OCs, since those are typically the 'victims' or 'losers' of the reform process, because factors of production are taken away from them.
The search for legitimising principles which support the complex ordering of this 'creative destruction' leads to the question of how to find Max Weber's quasi-religious normative order in contemporary China. Is there a modern, new Confucian combination of "command", "comprehensive, holistic responsibility", and "righteous leadership"?
In traditional imperial China the absolute power held by the emperor the 'son of heaven' was religiously legitimated by a (temporary) 'mandate of heaven'. After the civil war the CCP replaced this heavenly mandate by the quasi-religious 'mandate of history' of Marxist historical materialism, and in recent times the developmentalist economic-growth mandate of global capitalism was shrewdly incorporated. However, the predominant historic notion was not one of eternal bliss but of recurrently rising and falling dynasties, where empires fall once the terminable mandate of heaven (or history) is withdrawn. This concern still haunts the party when it pushes ideological campaigns like the last great one put forward by Jiang Zemin, namely ("Three Representations"), when in 1999 he led up to the preparations for the 16th party congress announcing that in the future, besides representing as the first group the "working class, peasants, and soldiers", namely the majority of the masses, the CCP will as a second group also represent the "advanced productive forces", among them profit-maximising entrepreneurs with privately owned means of production who, after the year of 2000, were finally allowed to enter the CCP, now being able to "draw on connections" () within the vanguard party structure itself , and as a third group the "progressive forces of the cultural sector".
In fact, much like in dynastic times, the leadership of the great chairmen Mao Zedong and Deng Xiaoping was not only built upon a mandate from 'heaven', but also upon a 'mystic', personal charisma in the same vain as Max Weber had put it in his other famous book "Economy and Society" (in the original German: Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, of 1925). It looks as if the Chinese have reclaimed their Confucian communist party 'virtue' as a synthesis of both Max Weber's "Protestant ethic" and his "charismatic power" clothed in chairman Mao chants, and that contemporary global 'developmentalism' represented by the famous saying of Deng Xiaoping: "It makes no difference whether a cat is black or white; as long as it catches mice, it is a good cat" (), reckoned as a justification for privatisation and socioeconomic stratification by legitimising the enrichissez-vous (enrich yourselves) of the new capitalist class.
This way of conducting politics on the side of the party leadership, and perceiving it on the side of the constituents, seems to rest "on a deep-seated belief in the sacrosanct nature of political authority and in the categorical differentiation between the ruler and the ruled" (Zhou, 2005:170-171). And this might, in fact, explain why the authoritarian power of the Chinese Communist Party is rather widely accepted among the Chinese people and also among entrepreneurs. The citizens of the People's Republic of China even seem to respect () the vanguard role of the assembly of party secretaries, perhaps just because the latter do exactly what noble men () in the ideal Confucian society are supposed to do: they take care () of other people. After all, power and righteousness are two sides of the same coin in the characteristics of every mode of governance. The political system of the People's Republic of China has thus kept a (tiny) window 'open' to change, if not revolt or even revolution in the case of non-righteousness, and also to the rise of those 'subjects' to become 'rulers' themselves, who adhere to the generally accepted rites () and the ideology of the vanguard party, thus enhancing competition, innovation, and elite rotation among 'old' and 'new' party secretaries. Unlike, for instance, Aristotle, the classical Confucian thinker Xunzi believed "that men are born equal in all ethically relevant respects" (Rosemont, 2000:4); and that "children [...] cry with the same voice at birth, but as they grow older they follow different customs. Education causes them to differ" ( , Watson, 1963:15). Consequently, every man has the got the ability to become a 'noble man' (an ideal ruler), when he has learned to follow 'the way' (). He argues: "The gentleman is by birth no different from any other man; it is just that he [...] [has become] good at making use of things" (, Watson, 1963:16).
Indeed and with respect to the CCP, in the course of the reform period, it has become highly attractive for mainland Chinese to enter the 'vanguard' party and to make a career as party secretaries on the various levels. In 1995, the Chinese Communist Party in fact experienced its largest increase of membership since the end of the Cultural Revolution (Wibowo, 2000:4), and the above mentioned competition and elite rotation within the party finally remind us of the structure of the ideal Confucian society, where every man has received the natural ability to become a noble man () himself.
The fact that in contemporary China this 'noble' party secretary keeps a share of the entrepreneurial profits for himself is not contradictory to Confucian thought at all: While making a career as a 'noble man', the party secretary is allowed to make profits (), as long as he puts weight on righteousness () ( VII 15, XIV 12, XVI 10; Bao and Lao, 1992:117, 239, 289). Notice: As long as the other creditors (OC) believe that the party secretary will act like a traditional 'noble man', i.e., that he will adhere to righteousness () in accordance with generally accepted rénqíng principles and Confucian traditions, they will also accept his self-interest in keeping a share of the entrepreneurial profits.
So far, the legitimacy of the 'grand design' of the social credit chain between the Communist Party, the traditional wealth owners, the assembly of party secretaries, the Schumpeterian entrepreneurs, the employed and the unemployed labourers, and the other creditors has not yet been broken. However, there always looms the danger that the powerful will lose their 'mandate of heaven' and their usurped 'will of the people' (volonté générale). Obviously fearing an upcoming legitimacy crisis at the dawn of the 11th five-years planning horizon (2006-10) since China is facing growing regional income disparities corresponding with rising unrest among the poor in the hinterland (Chen and Wu, 2006), and in order to meet the expectations of the 'masses' for social balance , state president Hu Jintao in 2004/05 unsealed the campaign of a "scientific concept of development" () combined with his vision of a "harmonious socialist society" () (Holbig, 2005). Against this background, the tense discussion about the equal protection of state and private property and the reform of the "re-education through labour" system at the National People's Congress in March 2007 shows clearly the tightrope walk the CCP follows with its global developmentalist approach.
On the side of the entrepreneurs, those economic agents so far not only seem to respect the authoritarian rule of the Communist Party secretaries, but they are even eager to make use of their mutual , in order to receive privileged access to real assets and human capital, as Howard Davies and coauthors (1995) discovered in their survey on business strategies of Hong Kong entrepreneurs with mainland Chinese. No wonder that their cry for democratic reforms along Western lines is not all too loud (Joffe, 2003) this seems to be especially true since, as already mentioned, entrepreneurs after 2000 have been able to gain even more privileged access to resources since being accepted as party members.
An authoritarian vanguard party system would become dysfunctional if it were not based upon a certain degree of mutual trust between the various economic agents beyond party members in a comprehensive, all-encompassing way. There must exist not only some sort of quasi-religious varnish, but also, in more practical terms, an universally accepted 'currency' for 'deferred payments' honouring medium and long-term obligations beyond the purely pecuniary sphere in the Chinese communist society. The official Renminbi or Yuan is mainly used for transaction purposes and, of course, increasingly also in the fledgling monetary economy with its formal financial markets, but obligations and claims bridging past, present, and future have only slowly and recently been denominated in Yuan terms.
How, then, is confidence among debtors and creditors involved in economic transactions created and expressed? Why should any local d nwèi party secretary or director supply real assets to any Schumpeterian entrepreneur, if he couldn't expect, with high probability, at least some kind of remuneration for himself and for his OC-constituency in the future? Especially if a certain deal is based upon an informal, relational forward credit contract why should the former wealth owner put any trust into his counterpart, believing that he, or somebody else, will be willing and able to pay back an informal loan in the future? In short: is there an equivalent to money? The answer to this question is again gu nxi, together with those already mentioned rénqíng principles, based upon traditional Confucian rites (), humaneness (), trust or reliability (), and righteousness (). Just like the central bank refinances Schumpeter's banker, when instead of sight and saving deposit services (which he can deliver himself), the wealth owner and the worker want to see the universally accepted cash (which he cannot produce himself), the Communist Party 'refinances' the individual PS (figure 7).
Party members, and party secretaries in particular, in all the administrations and enterprises involved take care of the victims honouring the explicit or implicit, actual or virtual promises like 'vouchers' (quasi-bank notes) that they receive for giving up their control over the resource. The party members can thus provide the ER with the necessary inputs, amenities and permits, and look after the necessary infrastructure so that a coherent accumulation process under the joint leadership of the private entrepreneur and the party can take place.
However, in the case of an emergency (equivalent to a 'run' on the bank), Bagehot's rule should apply here, too: "Lend freely, at a penalty rate, against good collateral!" As long as the individual PS behaves and performs well, the local assembly of PSs and the upper echelons of the party are willing to bail him out and 'refinance' his debt, albeit with rising remuneration rates. As in the Schumpeterian world, the entrepreneur has to compensate his PS, be it in cash, resources or reputation, and along the relevant lines, the PS has to 'pay' for his refinancing and to remunerate his fellow party members and his superiors in money or more importantly in terms of political support and by using his own distributing powers to 'refinance' his comrades with resource access, permits and other 'command' measures at his own disposal, when they themselves help an entrepreneur to start a business ex nihilo. It may sound anathema to compare a communist party with a central bank, but do not both of them provide the universal means for the allocation of resources and for the payment of debts in society? Do they not both separate the haves from the have-nots? And, above all, do not both of them guarantee coherence of the economy?
Furthermore, similarly to monetary economies, it is hard to find any 'fundamentals' for those trust chains in the real Chinese economy. Therefore, the whole building might crash and the motor might run in the rear gear, as soon as the participating economic agents lose faith in the Confucian principles. In this case, command ex nihilo can indeed also turn into a trust (= credit) crunch throwing the whole economy in nihil (into nothing). Anticorruption campaigns and other moralising endeavours of the ruling party are thus of more than accidental importance, since they resemble banking supervision measures in monetary economies, if not puritan sermons. A look at the further developments of the Chinese case in recent years should shed a light on the question, whether this distinction between a economy and a capitalist monetary economy should be looked upon as a categorical or a gradual one.
4. Political development banking: economics everywhere
In order to understand the dynamics of the Chinese economy, a closer look at the individual actors is warranted. What has actually happened underneath the formal institutions during the second phase of the economy, when the open 'command' phase was over? The monobank was transformed into a diversified banking system, including development banks promoting investment of enterprises of all kinds along political priorities, but not necessarily irrespective and unscrutinised with regard to economic viability. Both the PS and the former WO, or better, its former directors, have step by step become either entrepreneurs or remained politicians or administrators, or have become rentiers in the sense of persons of private means enjoying the rent they had sought in the previous phase, as bond or shareholders of the newly founded innovative enterprises (with or without foreign investors, who are not treated separately here, because that would open up a different topic, without adding substantial value to our basic argument). The OCs have or have not been indemnified for their sacrifices, and if you include nature here, the grave ecological problems of China pinpoint to the fact that she has never had a voice in any human society, and that monetary, socialist, and economies unfortunately do not seem to diverge much on that issue. Without advocates such as non-governmental organisations and committed individuals, with access to the media and legislatures, i.e., without freedom for the formation of public opinion, there is not even much hope for the better, when the standard of living improves while nature suffers.
The situation of the PS deserves special attention as a quite peculiar one, because we are talking about a socialist state, where collective ownership remains large, if not dominant. The PS might have become an economic agent throughout the reform process, but he still is primarily a political agent who remains responsible for the tasks and orders he receives not only from his superiors and peers, but also from the local members of the vanguard party with its claim to comprehensive, holistic responsibility, on which it is also held responsible, even in the guided media in China. In order to shield himself from political as well as personal responsibility, he has every incentive to leave more and more routine decisions to the new banks, which are increasingly taking over those functions which commercial banks have in capitalist monetary economies. In addition, with the rise of private property the power of the party is waning, since markets 'run by themselves', without the interference of visible party hands and thus without the need for as an essential trait of the dominant mode of production.
When only major investment decisions are left to the highest echelons of bank governance, the situation begins to resemble the one of ordinary politicians in all countries of the world, who try to direct credit and investment according to political criteria, without necessarily being members of a single 'vanguard' party. That is why our abbreviation in figure 8 changes from PS (party secretary of the CCP) to PN (ordinary politician everywhere).
Political (development) banking has been known in all contemporary economies, and on closer looks, every major innovative investment needs not only a commercial banker and functioning asset and labour markets, as implied in Schumpeter's model, but it also needs permits, accompanying infrastructure investment, and the solution of output market and raw material access problems beyond market forces so that trust and mutual confidence among persons from different social institutions turn out to be a rather universal trait of economic life. is supposedly the clue to contemporary China's economic growth, but there is evidence and logic in the assertion that it is not totally incompatible with a market economy and capitalist banking, because the 'local emperor' would lose much, but not necessarily all of his power in the transition process. It would even be compatible with multiparty democratisation, once coherence is no longer guaranteed by the party but by functioning markets and banks, including the central bank which does not even necessarily have to be independent. The more or less democratically elected PN might substitute the PS, once markets and money make the economy gradually 'run by itself'. The litmus test of who is winning the rivalry between the party and the market lies in the access to resources: Are they auctioned off in the marketplace, or adjudicated by administrative fiat? Which of the two allocation mechanisms with its concomitant superstructure becomes prevalent? The struggle for hegemony in Chinese society has only begun. No quick resolution is to be expected. After all, trends of authoritarian party rule along lines often creep into profoundly capitalist societies, be it on the national, the regional or quite usual the municipal level.
Thus, not only Schumpeter and Weber show themselves as rather reliable guides to the mysteries of contemporary Chinese growth, but also
economics turns out to be much more pervasive than being confined to China. However, nowhere else in history and space has the typically Chinese constellation evolved that puts personal trust and confident party backing into such an extremely important, pivotal place within a complex institutional structure that it could and should be called a mode of production sui generis. This setup was probably never designed by a mastermind, but it seems to be a peculiar trouvaille of history stemming from a stalemate within the CCP between reformers and conservatives, where privatisation in favour of entrepreneurs from the one hand side remained balanced by the predominance of public property and its gradual, if at all, transformation, and by the maintenance of absolute power by the party and its local secretaries on the other. A brief comparison with the Russian (and other East European) experience with transition or transformation, shows the singularity of the Chinese way.5. Big bang economics in Russia and beyond
Transformation from the socialist mode of production to other social formations takes different forms and paths. From our point of view, the 'big bang' reform path followed in Russia supports our argument.
Gorbachev loosened price controls within his perestroika policies, allowing enterprises to set their own prices and to run into debt with the monobank and its subsidiaries. This led to an accumulation of debts in the balance sheets of both state enterprises as status quo ante wealth owners, in our terms and banks. In the beginning, state bonds were offered to the banks crowding out loans to private entrepreneurs, which were officially encouraged, but lacked access to credit and capital (see figure 9).
It came to no surprise that over-indebted WOs and BKs did not attract the most serious and honourable businessmen when privatised, whatever the modalities, vouchers, management buyouts or outright sales, but fell into the hands of what was later called 'oligarchs' or 'mafias'.
When Boris Yeltsin held his speech before the Duma in 1991, dissolving and even forbidding the Communist Party of the Soviet Union, he broke the backbone of the "vanguard mode of production" (Lebowitz, 2000) without putting a functioning alternative into place. The economy crashed, because not even for simple reproduction were there the necessary conditions, let alone for growth. It took many years before recuperation set in, assisted by rising oil and gas prices. Another type of Russian trouvaille symbiosis between capitalist market structures and authoritarian rule has since developed whose analysis lies beyond the confines of this article.
6. Summary: intermediation matters
The puzzle of the microeconomics of Chinese growth can be approached, if not solved by asking for the institutions and mechanisms which guarantee the obviously high coherence and dynamism of economic decisions. Schumpeter had laid the foundations of the monetary theories of development in the pre-World War I period with its fabulous dynamism. His diagnosis of the social division of labour between Unternehmer, Bankier and Wirt, with the state as facilitator and night-watchman securing the property rights of the individuals in the capitalist mode of production, can be taken as the basic model to be modified according to the circumstances in contemporary China. Analogous to Schumpeter's bank loan, created ex nihilo between entrepreneur (ER) and bank (BK), it is the command and later the order to finance via the banks, that the party secretary (PS) of the all-powerful Communist Party of China (CCP) intermediates the transfer of resources between the status quo wealth owner (WO) and ER equally ex nihilo, because he himself does not own the resources nor does he rely on voluntary 'savings' from the side of WO. What he needs, however, is confidence in his ability to remunerate, one way or the other, not only the PS, but also the WO and its constituency of managers, owners, members, and other creditors (OC). When he cannot deliver, a crash in nihil might loom. Since a single PS is never able to come up with the necessary variety of goods and services to satisfy those requirements, he needs 'refinancing' from his fellow party comrades on all levels, who, in turn, draw on connections () on those claims in the cases of their own needs. Confidence beyond personal relations, with the party as quasi-clergy in a secularised, quasi-religious 'developmentalist' state, turns out to be the clue for understanding the dynamism of recent Chinese growth. is thus the magic word for trust, confidence, reliability, righteousness, mutual benefit and cosmic order, and it seems to be the magic thing in the contemporary Chinese economy.
In manuals on how to do business in contemporary China, the term is often explained and used, but seldom its institutionalised, constitutive character for the working of the whole economic system is identified and described, as we have tried here. In contrast to the Russian experience suffice it to stress the point e contrario that coherence is crucial for every economy, which can be achieved through various institutional arrangements and regimes. And in order to grow beyond the stationary state of a more or less coherent equilibrium, Schumpeter is right to stress that institutionalised intermediation (IN) between WO and ER is decisive, when the entrepreneur can count on profits based on innovations (see figure 10). Unfortunately, his "creative destruction" is not always balanced in favour of creation, but can have a very destructive social and ecological bias, as China shows, as well as all the other countries with economic growth. And Weber is also right in emphasising that some kind of religious 'spirit' is essential for accumulation and that the theological foundations of those blessings can be rather different from the lessons and prescriptions their epigones are drawing from the 'holy' scripts, be it the (, Analects of Confucius), the Bible, or the Communist Manifesto.
Within the mode of production approach to the theory of economic growth and development, the ' economy' of contemporary China occupies a rather unique position. Real socialism with public ownership of the means of production only seems to grow with Stalinist or Maoist oppression and campaigning, or it remains on the stage of Marx's "simple reproduction". In the capitalist mode, money sets the stage, and the interplay between private creditors and debtors is bundled into a coherent, dynamic whole by the central bank in the economic sphere and by more or less democratic institutions in the political arena. Combining the reproductive, care-taking traits of socialism with the entrepreneurial dynamism of private property through the Communist Party's guaranteeing coherence makes an ingenious institutional setup.
With a trend of gradually channelling the directives through banks, the system could become more and more compatible with capitalist market structures, and with asset markets and rule-of-law instead of visible-hand procedures in public administration, it could even turn into a democratic political system with various freely elected political parties (PP) for a sovereign Legislature (LG), an Eexecutive (EX), a legal authority (LA), and an independent Judiciary (JU), as a possible positive vision for the future (figure 11).
However, our argument should not be interpreted as a normative model, but as an analytical tool. Nor should any kind of teleology or determinism be projected into it. Capitalist entrepreneurs are not necessarily liberal democrats pressing for a multiparty system, free media, an independent Judiciary, human rights etc., nor does the 'vanguard' PS give necessarily way to the democratic PN, and the OCs, let alone nature, are not automatically 'taken care of'. Ours is an evolutionary approach, with an open future, and one with probably still many astonishing trouvailles on its long march.
Appendix
Abbreviations
BoC Bank of China
BK bank
CB central bank
CO consumer
CCP Communist Party of China
ER entrepreneur
EX executive branch of government
IN intermediary
JU judiciary
LA legal authority
LE employed labour
LG legislature
LU unemployed labour
OC other creditor/s or/and owner/s
ODA Official Development Assistance
PBoC People's Bank of China
PN politician/s
PP political party/ies
PS party secretary/ies
ST state
WO wealth owner
- BAGEHOT, Walter. Lombard street: a description of the money market. [1873] London: John Wiley & Sons, 1999.
- BAKKEN, Børge. Norms, Values and cynical games with party ideology. In: BRØDSGAARD, Kjeld Erik; ZHENG, Yongnian (Eds.). Bringing the party back in: how China is governed. Singapore: Eastern Universities Press, 2004. p. 22-56.
- BAO, Shixiang; LAO, An. The analects of Confucius: a Chinese-English bilingual edition. Jinan: Shandong Friendship Press, 1992.
- CHEN, Guidi; WU, Chuntao. Zur Lage der chinesischen Bauern: eine Reportage. (German translation by Hans Peter Hoffmann.). Frankfurt am Main: Zweitausendeins, 2006. [The original Chinese: Zhongguó nóngmín diàochá , Beijing: Renmin chubanshe, 2004].
- DAVIES, Howard; LEUNG, Thomas K. P.; LUK, Sherriff T. K.; WONG. Yiu-hing: the benefits of "guanxi" the value of relationships in developing the Chinese market. Industrial Marketing Management, n. 24, p. 207-214, 1995.
- DIEBEL, Frank. Die Rolle des Parteisekretärs im Reformprozess: Ein Beitrag zur Erklärung binnenwirtschaftlicher Aspekte des chinesischen Wirtschaftswachstums durch Guanxi Economics aus monetär-keynesianischer Perspektive. Master's thesis Free University of Berlin, 2005. Available from: <www.frankdiebel.de>.
- EASTERLY, William. The ghost of financing gap: testing the growth models of the international m. financial institutions. Journal of Development Economics, v. 60, n. 2, p. 423-438, 1999.
- _________. The elusive quest for growth: economists' adventures and misadventures in the tropics. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2002.
- EISENSTADT, S. N. (Ed.). Max Weber on charisma and institution building: selected papers. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1968.
- FRIEDMAN, Milton. Money mischief New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1992.
- GUANGGUO, Huang. Rújia sixiang yu Dongyà xiàndàihuà [Confucianism and the modernisation of East Asia]. Taipei: Jùliú túshu gongsi, 1988.
- _________. Rénqíng yu miànzi: Zhongguórén de quánlì yóu xì [Humaneness and face: power games of the Chinese]. In: YANG, Guofu; LI, Yiyuan; WEN, Chongyi et al. (Eds.). Xiàndàihuà y Zhongguóhuà lùnjí [ Anthology for modernisation and sinisation). Taipei: Guìguan túshu gongsi chuban, 1990. Zhongguórén cóngshu , n. 9, p. 125-154.
- HERR, Hansjörg.Das Finanzsystem in der VR China. In: _____; SOMMER, Albrecht; HE, Zerong (Eds.). Nachholende Entwicklung in China: Geldpolitik und Restrukturierung. Berlin: Berlin School of Economics, 2002. (fhw-Forschung, n. 40/41, p. 21-51).
- HOLBIG, Heike. "Wissenschaftliches Entwicklungskonzept", "Harmonische Gesellschaft" und "Eigenständige Innovation": Neue parteipolitische Prioritäten unter Hu Jintao. China Aktuell, n. 6, p. 13-19, 2005.
- JOFFE, Gideon. Entstehung und Entwicklung des Unternehmertums in der VR China und sein Einfluss auf Transformation und Demokratisierung Köln: Eul, 2003.
- KIPNIS, Andrew B. Producing guanxi: sentiment, self, and subculture in a North China village. London: Duke University Press, 1997
- KLINE III, T. C.; IVANHOE, Philip J. (Eds.). Virtue, nature, and moral agency in the Xunzi Indianapolis: Hackett, 2000.
- KNOBLOCK, John. Xunzi: a translation and study of the complete works. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1988, 1990, 1994. 3 v.
- LAU, Kin Chi. Unzeitgemäße Betrachtungen über Modernisierung in China. Peripherie Zeitschrift für Politik und Ökonomie in der Dritten Welt, Münster: Westfälisches Dampfboot, n. 103, p. 255-290, Sept. 2006.
- LEBOWITZ, Michael A. Kornai and the vanguard mode of production. Cambridge Journal of Economics, n. 24, p. 377-392, 2000.
- LUO, Yadong. Guanxi and business Singapore: World Scientific, 2000. (Asia-Pacific Business Series, 1).
- MCKINNON, Ronald I. Money and capital in economic development Washington: Brookings, 1973.
- MORITZ, Ralf. Konfuzius: Gespräche (Lunyu) [Translation from Chinese]. 2. ed. Köln: Röderberg, 1989.
- NITSCH, Manfred. Vom Nutzen des monetär-keynesianischen Ansatzes für Entwicklungstheorie und -politik. In: SCHUBERT, Renate (Hg.). Neue Wachstums- und Außenhandelstheorie Implikationen für die Entwicklungstheorie und -politik. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, 1999. p. 183-214.
- _________. Strukturelle Heterogenität in Lateinamerika und Osteuropa. Vom Nutzen des . Produktionsweisen-Ansatzes für die Analyse von Akkumulation, (Unter-) Entwicklung und Transformation sowie für den Aufbau von basisorientierten Finanzinstitutionen. In: SCHORKOWITZ, Dittmar (Ed.). Transition Erosion Reaktion Zehn Jahre Transformation in Osteuropa. Frankfurt: M. Peter Lang, 2002. p. 91-129.
- PORCELLUZZI, Antonella Anna. Bagehot and the Open money supply approach. Doctoral thesis Freie Universität Berlin, 2005, Available from: <www.diss.fu-berlin.de/2005/220>.
- PRIEWE, Jan. Chinas rätselhaftes Wachstum. Intervention, Zeitschrift für Ökonomie: Journal of Economics, v. 2, n. 2, p. 21-32, 2005.
- RIESE, Hajo. Geld: Das letzte Rätsel der Nationalökonomie. In: _____. Grundlegungen eines monetären Keynesianismus ù Ausgewählte Schriften 1964-1999. Band 1: Das Projekt eines monetären Keynesianismus Metropolis. Marburg, 2001. p. 469-485.
- _________. Money, development and economic transformation: selected essays by Hajo Riese, edited by Jens Hölscher and Horst Tomann. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2004.
- ROSEMONT, Henry Jr. State and society in the Hsün Tzu: a philosophical commentary. Monumenta Serica 29 (1970-1) 38. In: KLINE III, T. C.; IVANHOE, Philip J. (Eds.). Virtue, nature, and moral agency in the Xunzi Indianapolis: Hackett, 2000. p. 1-38.
- SCHUMPETER, Joseph Alois. Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung: Eine Untersuchung über Unternehmergewinn, Kapital, Kredit, Zins und den Konjunkturzyklus. [1912] 4. ed. Leipzig: Duncker und Humblot, 1931. [English translation: The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, interest, and the business cycle. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press, 1934].
- SHAW, Edward S. Financial deepening in economic development New York: Oxford University Press, 1973.
- SHIRK, Susan L. The Chinese political system and the political strategy of economic reform. In: LIEBERTHAL, Kenneth G.; LAMPTON, David M. Bureaucracy, politics, and decision making in post-Mao China Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992.
- WATSON, Burton. Hsün Tzu: basic writings. New York: Columbia University Press, 1963.
- WEBER, Max. Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus (1905). In: _____. Die protestantische Ethik Eine Aufsatzsammlung. München: Siebenstern, 1965. [English translation: The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism New York: Scribner, 1958].
- _________. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft: Grundriss der verstehenden Soziologie. [1925]. 5. rev. Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), 1976.
- WIBOWO, Ignatius. The current state of the Communist Party in the countryside Singapore: World Scientific Publishing and Singapore University Press, 2000. (East Asian Institute, Contemporary China Series, 25).
- YANG, Mayfair Mei-hui. Gifts, favors and banquets: the art of social relationship in China. New York: Cornell University Press, 1994.
- ZHOU, Zhenghuan. Liberal rights and political culture: envisioning democracy in China. New York: Routledge, 2005.
Publication Dates
-
Publication in this collection
21 Feb 2008 -
Date of issue
Oct 2007